Category

Economy

Category

President Trump is not happy with Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell. With the economy likely to slow under the weight of the administration’s tariffs and corresponding uncertainty, the president thinks the Fed should be cutting rates preemptively. Powell, in contrast, prefers a wait-and-see approach, at least partially out of fear that inflation will resurge if the Fed cuts rates too soon.

In a Truth Social post last week, the president wrote that “Powell’s termination cannot come fast enough!”

Figure 1. Trump blasts Powell on Truth Social, April 17, 2025

Powell’s four-year term as chair will end on May 15, 2026. Even then, he could stay on the Board as a governor until January 31, 2028. President Trump had considered getting rid of Powell even sooner, but then more recently said he had ‘no intention’ of firing the chair.

The Federal Reserve Act permits the president to remove a governor “for cause.” (Powell would not be able to continue to serve as chair if he were removed as a governor.) It is widely accepted, however, that cause does not include mere policy disputes. That is certainly Powell’s view. When asked whether the president has the power to fire or demote the Fed chair back in November, Powell said it was “Not permitted under the law.” Just last week, he said the Fed’s “independence is a matter of law.”

President Trump disagrees. “If I want him out, he’ll be out of there real fast, believe me,” he said last week.

Earlier this year, then-Vice Chair for Supervision Michael Barr opted to step down before President Trump could attempt to fire or demote him, which seemed likely. Barr did not believe the president had the authority to do so, but did not “want to spend the next couple of years fighting about that” in court and thought “it would be a serious distraction from” the Fed’s “ability to serve our mission.”

Whether intentional or not, Barr’s decision has almost certainly improved the odds that Powell will serve out his term as chair. Since Barr was very unpopular among Republican lawmakers, President Trump would not have experienced much opposition from the home team for firing or demoting him. And, if Barr had fought the decision in court and lost, Trump could point to the precedent when dealing with Powell. By stepping down, Barr prevented such a precedent from being established.

Unlike Barr, Powell is very popular among Republican lawmakers. That puts the president in a much more difficult position. If he moves to fire or demote Powell, he will face opposition from some Republican lawmakers — and, since the decision might be overturned by the Courts anyway, it could be all cost and no benefit for the president.

When asked on Tuesday, President Trump said he has “no intention of firing” Powell. When reminded that, just a few days prior, National Economic Council Director Kevin Hassett indicated the president and people in the White House were studying the issue, President Trump denied that he had any plans to oust Powell. “None whatsoever. Never did,” the president said.

The press runs away with things. No, I have no intention of firing him. I would like to see him be a little more active in terms of his idea to lower interest rates. This is a perfect time to lower interest rates. If he doesn’t, is it the end? No, it’s not. But it would be good timing. It could have taken place earlier. But, no, I have no intention to fire him.

That would seem to put an end to the question.

If President Trump does not intend to fire Powell, how will he respond in the likely event that the Fed continues to delay cutting its federal funds rate target? (The CME Group currently puts the odds of a May rate cut at just 8.3 percent.)

Last year, now-Treasury Secretary Scott Bessent suggested Trump could appoint a “shadow Fed chair” prior to the end of Powell’s term. The shadow Fed chair would initially be appointed as a governor, with a credible commitment from the president that he or she would be elevated to chair once Powell’s term ends. The shadow Fed chair could then make speeches indicating how he or she would conduct policy in the future, which would move expectations — and markets — today.

There are at least three problems with Bessent’s suggestion, however. First, the Federal Open Market Committee conducts policy by majority vote. The Fed chair usually has an outsized voice in the process, but there is no guarantee that the remaining members of the FOMC would go along with the president’s new appointment when the time comes. The most recent Summary of Economic Projections and statements from FOMC members suggest there is broad support for Powell’s wait-and-see approach. If other FOMC members were to publicly oppose the future chair’s stated policy path, it would hamper his or her ability to move expectations as shadow chair.

Second, the president can only appoint a governor when a position becomes available. Barring a resignation or firing, the next opening will come in January 2026 when the balance of Adriana Kugler’s partial term ends. (Although she would then be eligible for reappointment, it is difficult to imagine President Trump extending the term of his predecessor’s pick.) Hence, a shadow chair would be left waiting in the wings until January — making any statements before then less credible than they would be if he or she were already on the Board.

Third, the shadow chair scheme risks significantly narrowing the pool of potential applicants. The power and independence of the Fed is part of the position’s appeal. I suspect few of those qualified and interested in the top spot would remain interested if they thought the shenanigans surrounding their appointment would significantly weaken the institution. The Wall Street Journal reports that Kevin Warsh, who is widely believed to be a frontrunner for the position, “has advised against firing Powell and has argued that he should let the Fed chair complete his term without interference.” If a chair-in-waiting were to appear complicit in a scheme to undermine the power and independence of the Fed, it would not merely damage the reputation of the Fed. It would damage the reputation of the chair-in-waiting, as well.

Given the constraints, it is easy to understand why President Trump now says he will not fire the Fed chair and, indeed, never intended to do so. As for appointing a shadow Fed chair, that seems unlikely, too. Most likely, the president will reluctantly let Powell serve out his term as chair while continuing to badger and berate him from the bully pulpit. Whether pressure from the president will be effective, ineffective, or counter-effective remains to be seen.

President Donald J. Trump recently signed an Executive Order directing the Secretary of Energy to rescind certain restrictions on water pressure established by his predecessors. 

As the White House put it, the president was ending the “Obama-Biden war on water pressure and [making] America’s showers great again.”

This isn’t the final salvo in the decades-long Appliance Wars — nor did the order accomplish what many on social media claim.

I first encountered the Appliance Wars in the 1990s, courtesy of my favorite TV show, Seinfeld. In a memorable episode, Kramer, Jerry, and Newman are all visibly irked (and unkempt) as they wrestle with the newly mandated “low-flow” showers.

“There’s no pressure; I can’t get the shampoo out of my hair!” Kramer laments. “If I don’t have a good shower, I am not myself. I feel weak and ineffectual; I’m not Kramer.”

The scene comes from “The Shower Head,” Season 7, Episode 15, which aired in 1996. I didn’t catch it until a few years later while in college, but even then the episode felt fresh, edgy, and smart. 

What I didn’t know was that the Appliance Wars had already been raging for decades.

The Appliance Wars

On December 22, 1975, President Gerald Ford signed into law the Energy Policy and Conservation Act, which granted the president powers over energy exports. The law included regulatory power over household appliances to increase energy efficiency.

The legislation was a response to the 1970s oil crisis, an event that was exacerbated by price controls imposed by President Richard Nixon. The first energy efficiency regulations under the EPCA focused primarily on items like refrigerators, air conditioners, and water heaters, but over time, the scope of these regulations expanded and became more stringent.

In 1992, the Energy Policy Act amended the EPCA to require stricter efficiency standards for appliances and water efficiency standards, including a rule that mandated lower-flow showerheads that limited outflows to 2.5 gallons of water per minute. 

The federal government’s attempt to save the planet by regulating showerheads seemed common sense to some and absurd to others. For writers at Seinfeld, it was clearly the latter. 

Yet the low-flow showers that Seinfeld mocked were not stringent enough for some. 

In 2010, the Obama Administration reduced the maximum flow of showerheads to 2.0 gallons per minute. Some states have gone further. California, for example, has regulations that limit the maximum flow rate for showerheads to 1.8 gallons (and 1.2 GPM for bath faucets).

Twitter and media were abuzz last week that Trump had “made showers great again,” but his executive order didn’t scrap the federal rule, something the White House’s own statement confirms.

“President Trump is restoring sanity to at least one small part of the federal regulations, returning to the straightforward meaning of ‘showerhead’ from the 1992 energy law, which sets a simple 2.5-gallons-per-minute standard for showers,” the press release stated.

The executive order reversed a complicated Biden rule — it was 13,000 words, according to the White House — on the definition of the word “showerhead.” What it did not do was repeal the 1992 regulation.

‘If Washington Can Regulate Showerheads’

The Trump administration is taking a victory lap for “Making Showers Great Again,” but the federal regulation that inspired “The Shower Head” is still in place — it’s just slightly less stringent than the 2-gallon per minute rule initiated during the Obama presidency. (To be fair, the 2.5 limit is written into the US Code, which cannot be changed with the stroke of a pen.) 

That episode ended with Kramer buying “hot” showerheads off the black market. The episode captured the absurdity of attempting to conserve resources in a top-down fashion. As Kramer pointed out, he couldn’t get clean with the new showerheads, which resulted in him taking longer showers. 

Longer showers are indeed a consequence of lower-flow showerheads, but these are the kind of practical consequences that rule-making bureaucrats rarely consider. We’re supposed to take it on faith that federal regulators know the optimal amount of water each individual requires to live, wash, and flush. They don’t, of course.

The Showerhead Wars are funny because they are a Kafkaesque absurdity. The wars lay bare the stupidity of a soulless bureaucracy that can spend 13,000 words defining the term “showerhead” to make our lives less enjoyable and efficient. 

The joke is ultimately on us. Because if Washington can regulate your showerhead, it can regulate anything — and that’s the problem.

We just made it through another tax season. Congress has begun debating whether and how to extend the Trump tax cuts from the 2018 Tax Cuts and Jobs Act. While many elements of that tax debate are worth commenting on, I want to highlight the standard deduction because it sheds light on an underappreciated part of American philanthropy.

Prior to the introduction of the federal income tax in 1913, charitable donations did not have meaningful tax deduction benefits. Yet Americans gave generously. In fact, if anything, American philanthropy has declined due to the Scrooge effect of the welfare state. “Are there no [state-funded] prisons [or work-houses]?” Ebenezer Scrooge asks in Charles Dickens’ A Christmas Carol.

The questions reveal that Scrooge (and others) feel that their higher taxes to fund a variety of social and “poverty-reduction” programs take the place of direct philanthropic giving. Americans also keep a lot less of what they earn today than they did a hundred or a hundred and fifty years ago—as most of us know from recent personal experience.

The case of welfare programs crowding out charity has been made eloquently by Marvin Olasky in The Tragedy of American Compassion. Various religious and fraternal orders provided health insurance, old-age insurance, and other social services to their members throughout the nineteenth and into the twentieth century. These services were later replaced by state unemployment benefit schemes, Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid.

These government programs “crowded out” charitable, philanthropic, civil society—contributing to problems of declining social capital elaborated by Robert Nisbet (Quest for Community) and Robert Putnam (Bowling Alone). Government agencies and government checks replaced civic networks and systems of support. Yet American philanthropy is still alive and kicking in the U.S.

The Lilly Family School of Philanthropy at Indiana University estimates that Americans gave $557.16 billion to charity in 2023. That’s about $1,600 per capita. By comparison, Canadians gave about $400 per capita to charity and Brits gave about $250 per capita. Even as a percentage of GDP, the U. S. ranks well above European countries. According to one source, the U. S. is one of the most charitable countries in the world.

What’s remarkable is that the vast majority of Americans who give to charity receive no federal tax benefit from doing so. Returning to the individual exemption, when you file your taxes, you can either claim the standard deduction ($14,600 for an individual, or $29,200 for a couple) or you can itemize your deductions. A few expenses can count towards the itemized deductions, but these expenses are highly qualified and don’t add up to much for the average person.

From a benefit standpoint, your qualified expenses, including your charitable giving, must add up to more than the standard deduction before you receive any tax advantage. Suppose someone takes the entire $10,000 state and local tax deduction (SALT) and comes up with $5,000 more in other qualified expenses. They would still be $14,200 short of the $29,200 standard deduction for a couple. This means that any of their charitable giving, up to $14,200, does not render them any benefits on their federal taxes. 

Seventy percent of American households earn less than $127,000 before taxes. So $14,200 would mean donating more than ten percent of their pre-tax earnings before they saw any advantage from the giving being “tax-deductible.” For most Americans, the “tax-deductible” element of charitable giving is practically irrelevant. Yet they give anyway.

Most Americans donate money even though they receive no federal tax benefit. Americans gave generously long before the income tax and the charitable tax deduction existed. A large industry of lawyers and accountants has cropped up to help wealthy people lower their tax liabilities through various forms of charitable giving. Sometimes these methods lead to creative accounting and legal gymnastics that can distort or divert people’s choices of how to use their wealth.

These observations provide a few reasons to want an alternative to our federal tax code 501(c)(3) structure. We should ask whether society would be freer in a world without tax exemptions for charitable giving—a world without the stark for-profit/nonprofit legal divide with all its attendant reporting and hoops. Tax code rules that put their thumb on the scale represent social engineering of the kind free people should reject.

Most Americans give generously without thought of return—even with a large welfare state and high taxes. There is something deeply admirable about this kind of generosity that gives without expecting any material benefit in return. Imagine how they would give if the welfare state were trimmed down and their taxes were lower. That’s what George W. Bush’s “compassionate conservatism” should have meant.

The school choice revolution just scored its most historic victory yet. The Texas House passed Senate Bill 2 by a decisive vote of 86 to 63, following the Texas Senate’s approval by a 19 to 12 margin.  

Texas Senate leadership announced Friday that the chamber plans to concur next week with the version of the bill passed by the House. Shortly afterwards, Governor Greg Abbott announced that he is “ready to sign this bill into law.” 

This isn’t just a win for Texas families — it’s the biggest day-one school choice initiative in US history, launching a $1 billion Education Savings Account (ESA) program for 100,000 students. The initiative provides about $10,000 per child for private school tuition or other educational expenses, with more funding for students with disabilities. Homeschool families would receive $2,000 per student per year for approved education expenses.  

Texas is the sixteenth state to pass universal school choice since 2021, cementing red states as the vanguard of parental rights in education. 

Texas’s journey to this moment was fraught with resistance. Just last year, 21 Texas House Republicans joined all Democrats to vote against school choice, sinking Governor Greg Abbott’s school choice proposal in 2023. But the political winds have shifted dramatically. After the 2024 primaries, only seven of those Republicans remained in office, thanks to Abbott’s relentless campaign to oust anti-school choice incumbents.  

On Thursday, six of those seven holdouts flipped, voting in favor of universal school choice, signaling a seismic realignment in the Texas House. This turnaround underscores the growing clout of parents and the electoral peril of standing in their way. 

The spark for this parent-led revolution came from an unlikely source: Randi Weingarten and the teachers’ unions. By fighting to keep schools shuttered during the COVID era, they gave parents a front-row seat to the Marxist critical race theory and gender ideology infiltrating public school curricula.  

Outraged and galvanized, parents became a political juggernaut, demanding control over their children’s education. Their influence fueled Donald Trump’s landslide victory in November 2024, driven by a nine-point lead among parents — a 15-point shift from 2020, when they favored Joe Biden by 6 points.  

The result is staggering: about 40 percent of America’s school-age population now lives in states with universal school choice policies — a meteoric rise from zero percent in 2021. 

Red states like Texas, Florida, Arizona, and Iowa are setting the standard for parental empowerment, recognizing that families, not bureaucrats, know what’s best for their kids. Florida, once a swing state, shows how school choice reshapes politics. In 2018, Ron DeSantis narrowly won his first gubernatorial election because school choice moms rallied behind him after his Democrat opponent, Andrew Gillum, vowed to dismantle the state’s scholarship program.  

Those parents tipped the scales, and today, Florida Republicans boast supermajorities in both the House and Senate. School choice isn’t just the right thing to do — it’s a political winner for Republicans, helping them make inroads with voters who might otherwise lean Democrat. Families desperate for better education options become single-issue voters, rewriting the political playbook. 

Meanwhile, blue states are doubling down on policies that alienate parents, ignoring the mandate from Trump’s parent-driven victory. In Colorado, Democrats passed House Bill 25-1312, classifying “misgendering” your own child as child abuse, potentially ripping away children from their parents if they refuse to affirm the delusions of a small child.  

In Illinois, Democrats eliminated the state’s modest school choice program in 2023 and are now targeting homeschooling freedom with House Bill 2827. This bill, which advanced out of committee on a party-line vote last month, would force homeschooling families to file annual declarations, disclose detailed personal information about their children, and submit to portfolio reviews by public school officials, with truancy charges or misdemeanor penalties for non-compliance.  

These policies aren’t just out of touch — they’re a direct assault on parents’ rights to direct their children’s upbringing. 

The political consequences of ignoring parents are clear. In Virginia’s 2021 gubernatorial race, former Governor Terry McAuliffe handed victory to Glenn Youngkin by dismissing parental concerns, infamously stating, “I don’t think parents should be telling schools what they should teach.” That misstep ignited a parent-led backlash, proving parental rights are a third rail in politics. Democrats better learn this lesson soon if they want to stay in office.  

School choice enjoys overwhelming bipartisan support — 71 percent of voters back it, including 80 percent support among Republicans and 69 percent support among independents. Even Democrats privately concede it’s a winning issue, but their loyalty to teachers’ unions keeps them tethered to a losing strategy. 

School choice is more than better education — it’s a pathway for Republicans to expand their majorities by appealing to diverse voters. When families see their kids thriving in schools that align with their values, they don’t just vote — they mobilize. In Arizona, universal school choice passed in 2022 and has become a cornerstone of family empowerment. Once parents gain the power to choose, they fight like hell to keep it, and politicians who try to claw it back face political consequences.  

The teachers’ unions thought they could hold education hostage, but they’ve awakened a sleeping giant. Parents are now a more potent voting bloc than union bosses, reshaping the political landscape.  

Texas’s Senate Bill 2 marks a national turning point, showing that empowering parents is both good policy and smart politics. Republicans are building coalitions across racial, economic, and geographic lines, as Texas’s shift from 21 Republican holdouts in 2023 to a pro-school choice majority in 2025 demonstrates. Democrats in blue states are running out of time to adapt. The longer they cling to policies like Colorado’s HB 25-1312 or Illinois’s HB 2827, the more they risk political suicide. 

The parent revolution is here to stay, and red states are leading the way. As Texas joins the ranks of school choice pioneers, the message to union-controlled politicians is clear: empower parents or prepare to lose.  

The days of top-down control over education are numbered. Families are taking back their power, and won’t give up without a fight.

In times of rising debt and fiscal strain, unconventional ideas occasionally surface as ways to manage the US government’s borrowing obligations. Few have forgotten the trillion-dollar platinum coin scheme a few years back. A recent suggestion, associated with Stephen Miran’s A User’s Guide to Restructuring the Global Trading System (a.k.a. The Mar-a-Lago Accord) involves forcing or pressuring holders of US Treasury securities to exchange their current bonds—many with short- or medium-term maturities—for 100-year bonds carrying lower interest rates. 

On the surface, the plan seems attractive: it could reduce short-term debt servicing costs and push out repayment far into the future. However, viewed through legal, financial, and market lenses, the plan is a nonstarter—at best unrealistic, and if pursued, potentially disastrous. 

Below are seven key reasons why such a strategy would be unworkable and harmful to the credibility of the US government and the functioning of global financial markets.

1. It represents a violation of the contractual terms

Treasury securities are formal contracts between the US government and investors. They specify the amount borrowed, the coupon rate, and the repayment date. Investors buy these securities with the legally binding expectation that the terms will be honored. A forced conversion into 100-year bonds—particularly those with lower yields—would represent a breach of contract. This would likely result in a wave of legal challenges in US courts and could be interpreted as a selective default by credit rating agencies. More broadly, it would send a chilling message to investors that the US government cannot be relied upon to meet its obligations under previously agreed terms. That reputational damage would have lasting consequences for the government’s ability to borrow in the future.

(Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)

2. Dumping or another form of retaliation is likely

Foreign governments and central banks are among the holders of US Treasury securities, holding trillions of dollars’ worth as part of their currency reserves and financial stabilization strategies. If these entities were forced to exchange their existing holdings for ultra-long-term, lower-yielding bonds, they might interpret it as an act of bad faith or even financial expropriation. In response, some could retaliate economically or strategically, but most would likely begin to liquidate their Treasury holdings—either to avoid further exposure or as a form of protest. A coordinated or large-scale selloff by foreign holders would depress bond prices, push yields higher, and potentially weaken the dollar. The resulting financial instability would erode the US government’s long-standing position as the issuer of the world’s reserve currency.

3. There are considerable legal and political obstacles

Any plan to convert existing Treasury debt into 100-year bonds would encounter immense legal and political resistance. Congress would likely need to pass enabling legislation, and bipartisan opposition would be fierce, likely citing both the Contract Clause and the Takings Clause. Lawmakers across the ideological spectrum would view the measure as a direct threat to the full faith and credit of the United States. Moreover, contract law strongly protects the rights of bondholders, and retroactively changing debt terms would almost certainly be challenged in court. The only conceivable workaround—invoking emergency executive powers—would trigger a constitutional crisis and further erode domestic and international trust in US governance. The political fallout would be severe, and the financial markets would respond accordingly.

4. 100-year bonds with low yields are an unlikely and unattractive outcome

From a financial perspective, longer-term bonds carry substantially more risk than shorter-term ones. Investors exposed to longer maturities face greater uncertainty over inflation, interest rates, and creditworthiness. As a result, markets demand higher, not lower, yields for longer-term bonds. Forcing or even encouraging investors to accept lower-yielding 100-year bonds in exchange for their existing securities contradicts this basic principle of finance. The scale of this mismatch is glaring: a 1-year Treasury converted into a 100-year bond represents a 100-fold increase in maturity; even a 30-year bondholder would be tripling their time exposure. Yet the plan proposes that these investors accept lower compensation for that additional risk—a proposition that defies economic logic.

Further complicating matters are the bond market dynamics of duration and convexity. Duration measures how sensitive a bond’s price is to changes in interest rates. A bond with high duration—like a 100-year bond—will see its price fall significantly if interest rates rise even modestly. Convexity, which describes how a bond’s duration changes as interest rates move, becomes more pronounced in ultra-long bonds. While convexity can help slightly in very large interest rate swings, it also introduces greater pricing volatility and uncertainty, making 100-year bonds particularly hard to hedge or model. For many investors—especially those with liability-matching needs or regulatory constraints—this makes such instruments unappealing or outright unmanageable.

Finally, these ultra-long bonds would be less useful as collateral in the banking system. Treasury securities are widely used in repo markets and other secured lending arrangements because of their liquidity and relatively stable pricing. But the longer the maturity, the more volatile the market value—meaning that 100-year bonds would need to be deeply discounted (with a higher “haircut”) when used as collateral. This reduces their effective value in day-to-day financial operations and makes them a poor substitute for the shorter- and medium-term Treasuries currently in wide circulation. Additionally, their low liquidity and lack of historical issuance would make them harder to price and trade efficiently, further diminishing their utility in modern financial systems.

5. It would set a negative precedent and ratchet up moral hazard

The long-term consequences of forcing a debt restructuring would extend beyond the immediate market shock. If the US government sets the precedent that it can change repayment terms unilaterally—even in pursuit of efficiency or cost savings—it opens the door to future manipulations. Investors would begin to price in the risk that terms might change again under future administrations or during future crises. This creates a “moral hazard” problem where the government is seen as an unreliable borrower, ultimately raising borrowing costs and damaging its credit rating. More broadly, such a move could encourage other indebted nations to follow suit, weakening the integrity of sovereign debt markets globally. For a country that issues the world’s reserve currency and whose bonds underpin the global financial system, the risks of setting such a precedent are especially grave.

(Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)

6. Maturity stretching solves no fiscal ill

Even if the market accepted a swap of shorter-term debt for 100-year bonds—at appropriately higher yields to reflect the vastly longer exposure—such a maneuver would do nothing to resolve the underlying structural fiscal imbalance. It would merely change the timing of repayments, not their scale or structure. The central issue is not the maturity profile of US debt, but the chronic mismatch between government spending and revenue. As long as deficits persist—year after year—the total debt will continue to rise regardless of how it is financed. The debt problem will only be addressed when the deficit problem is resolved. That means aligning federal spending more closely with tax revenues through either fiscal consolidation, revenue increases, or both. Until that occurs, restructuring debt maturities is just a cosmetic change, not a real solution.

7. It could lead to a loss of confidence and market panic

Investor confidence is the cornerstone of stable financial markets, and US Treasury bonds are the global benchmark for low-risk assets precisely because of their reliability and predictability. If the government were to unilaterally alter the terms of its debt—extending maturities and lowering yields—investors would perceive this as a form of financial coercion or soft default. Such a move would spark a massive selloff in Treasury markets, drive up yields across the curve, and destabilize global portfolios that rely on Treasuries as a safe store of value. Broader market volatility would likely follow, including sharp declines in equities and liquidity freezes in credit markets. The ripple effects could extend to emerging market economies, corporate bond markets, and even the real economy through higher borrowing costs.

While the idea of reducing interest costs by converting existing debt into ultra-long, low-yielding bonds might sound like a creative solution to America’s debt challenges, it fails every test of financial realism, legal integrity, and political viability. It would violate contracts, damage the United States’ reputation as a trustworthy borrower, shake global confidence, reduce the usefulness of Treasuries in collateral markets, and set a damaging precedent for fiscal governance. Worse, even if done at market-clearing interest rates, it would not address the structural driver of debt growth: persistent federal deficits. Rather than stabilizing public finances, such a move would almost certainly ignite a full-blown financial crisis. In a world that still (and somehow inexplicably) depends on US debt markets, tampering with that foundation carries more risk than reward.

In 2021, the Biden administration secured $42.5 billion from Congress to extend broadband Internet access to small and ever-shrinking portions of the country that didn’t yet have it. Four years later, that federal program still hasn’t connected one single person to the Internet.  

Elon Musk’s DOGE efforts have so far uncovered tens of billions more in “waste, fraud, and abuse.” For example, the $40 billion USAID budget, DOGE found, is bloated with billions for indefensible bilge — from sex changes in Guatemala to tourism in Egypt. 

Is there anyone in his right mind who would argue that the federal government stimulated the economy by this spending? Or if the money instead had been left in the private sector, it would have hurt the economy? Is it humanly possible to waste other people’s money more thoroughly than the government does?  

Imagine a pickpocket who steals cash from the wallets and purses of unsuspecting shoppers in a mall. Then he goes from store to store and spends the loot. Whether or not he stimulated the mall economy depends on who you interview — shopkeepers who are grateful for the pickpocket’s patronage or the thief’s dispirited victims who discover they must go home empty-handed. 

When we employ our instinctive common sense, especially if we zero in on egregious and inexcusable profligacy, we are drawn to the conclusion that Milton Friedman expressed so well: “Nobody spends somebody else’s money as carefully as he spends his own.” Moreover, robbing Peter to pay Paul makes Paul richer but Peter equally poorer at the least. 

But if we adopt a Keynesian “macro” perspective, we will assert that more government spending energizes economic activity, and that less government spending sends the economy into a tailspin. Is it not simply amazing that politicians possess such powers the rest of us do not?! When they spend your money, the magical multiplier kicks in, but when you and I spend our money (or save it in the bank so the bank can spend it), we just don’t get the same bang for the buck. Just think how prosperous we would be if we laundered everything through the government (like they do in poverty-stricken North Korea). 

John Maynard Keynes himself once claimed that if the government simply paid people to dig holes and fill them back in, we could stimulate the economy. It didn’t matter to him what the government spent it for so long as it was the government doing the spending. In any event, he flippantly declared, “In the long run, we’re all dead anyway.”  

If DOGE ends up cutting federal expenditures by the trillion dollars or more that Musk has promised, expect every unrepentant Keynesian to warn of dire consequences. It would be the same wrong-headed thinking that led Keynesians in the 1940s to predict another depression when World War II ended.  

If another depression is in our future, it will not occur because government spends less. When it did spend less — decisively less — after World War II, depression didn’t materialize. Just the opposite. 

Under the influence of the Keynesian consensus, a committee chaired by New York Senator James Mead issued a report in 1945. It argued that with the imminent end of the war, “the United States would find itself largely unprepared to overcome unemployment on a large scale.” Even President Harry Truman, in September of that year, told The New York Times that it was “obvious” that the process of reducing federal employment and spending would yield “a great deal of inevitable unemployment.” Indeed, between June 1945 and June 1946, more than ten million people were lopped off the federal payroll (mostly military), and millions returned from overseas to the US job market, while Keynesians held their breath and expected the worst. 

One of the best assessments of what actually happened, in contrast to the Keynesian forecasts echoed by future Nobel laureates Paul Samuelson and Gunnar Myrdal, is that of economist David Henderson. In a November 2010 paper for the Mercatus Center titled The US Post-War Miracle, Henderson noted, 

In the four years from peak World War II spending in 1944 to 1948, the US government cut spending by $72 billion — a 75-percent reduction. It brought federal spending down from a peak of 44 percent of gross national product (GNP) in 1944 to only 8.9 percent in 1948, a drop of over 35 percentage points of GNP. 

While government spending fell like a stone, federal tax revenues fell only a little, from a peak of $44.4 billion in 1945 to $39.7 billion in 1947 and $41.4 billion in 1948. In other words, from peak to trough, tax revenues fell by only $4.7 billion, or 10.6 percent. Yet, the economy boomed. The unemployment rate, which was artificially low at the end of the war because many millions of workers had been drafted into the US armed services, did increase. But during the years from 1945 to 1948, it reached its peak at only 3.9 percent [italics mine] in 1946, and, for the months from September 1945 to December 1948, the average unemployment rate was only 3.5 percent. 

Let that sink in: Federal spending plummeted by 75 percent. Millions re-entered the private job market. Yet unemployment remained lower than it is today, and the economy took off. Keynesians, with all their vaunted “New Economics” and sophisticated equations, got it dead wrong. Common sense would have served them much better. 

One reason for the unexpected post-war “economic miracle” was the Revenue Act of 1945. Go to the search engine Bing.com. Type in “top corporate income tax rate 1944,” tap “Enter” and voila! The resulting number is staggering: 94 percent. Next, just change one digit in your search terms, from 1944 to 1945. The new figure? 38 percent. The Revenue Act cut marginal tax rates (on both business and personal income) a little, but more importantly, it eliminated surtaxes such as an “excess profits tax” that had driven rates so high. 

You need only common sense, no equations required, to know that there’ll be a whole lot more risk-taking entrepreneurship and business investment when you cut tax rates dramatically.  

Another reason for the boom was the abolition of all price controls. We had plenty of them during the war, but by 1946, they were all gone. Prices were freed to reflect supply and demand conditions in the marketplace, not the arbitrary whims of Congress or bureaucracies. The rationing of consumer goods ended as well. 

Prone to mathematize and oversimplify, Keynesians love to boil an economy down to three main components: Consumption plus Investment plus Government Spending, they claim, equals GNP.  C + I + G = Y is the Keynesian formula we all had to learn from our Keynesian economics profs. Their ideological bias prevented them from understanding that when there’s a lot less G, there’s a lot more C and I. That’s because ultimately, G has nothing that it doesn’t sooner or later take from C and I. This would be true even if G didn’t waste a penny. 

Common sense tells me that the 75 percent reduction in federal spending after the war may have been the most significant contributor to the economic boom. It diverted resources away from blowing things up on the battlefield. Instead, we could now make cars, refrigerators, and an array of consumer goods of which Americans had been deprived for years. At the very least, the Keynesian fear that massive government spending cuts would tank the economy proved to be utterly and embarrassingly unfounded. 

The US boom was no outlier. Once post-war Germany under Ludwig Erhard placed its faith in markets instead of government spending, the world began referring to “the German economic miracle.” Japan experienced a “Japanese economic miracle” for similar reasons. Hong Kong pursued smaller government/free-market policies after the war and awed the world with decades of phenomenal growth. Meantime, under a new socialist government, Britain plunged headlong into an expensive welfare state and became, by the 1970s, the “sick man of Europe.” 

In the 1980s, New Zealand transformed itself from a slow-growth welfare state into a free and vibrant economy. In just two years, it slashed government spending from 60 percent of GDP to 40 percent. Once again, Keynesians expected a bust, but the country got a boom instead. 

Some people besotted with Keynesian hangovers are worried that if DOGE cuts federal spending a lot, the American economy will lose the “stimulus” we somehow get from it all. But considering both common sense and the historical track record, our biggest concern should be that DOGE won’t cut enough. 

The US constitutional system of checks and balances, designed to stop any individual or institution from accumulating excessive power, has been compromised. Over time, Congress has delegated significant authority to the executive branch, including the power to appoint agency heads, execute policy-directing executive orders, act unilaterally on diplomatic and military matters, control the federal bureaucracy, and exert broad authority over trade relations.

Under the Trump administration, the Unitary Executive doctrine has expanded. This theory holds that the US Constitution gives the president complete control over the executive branch and thus can fire agency heads or inspectors general at will. This weakens agency independence and internal checks such as whistleblowers, leaving agencies such as the SEC or EPA open to politicization. The Supreme Court’s ruling in Trump v. US confirmed absolute immunity for official acts, further shielding presidential actions from accountability. While interpretations of the Unitary Executive doctrine may vary, its expansion has greatly increased executive power.

Political developments have only increased this erosion. Legislators, fearful of primary challenges, and CEOs, wary of presidential retribution, have both weakened institutional independence. As a result, sweeping policy and regulatory changes now face fewer obstacles. James Madison’s vision in the Federalist Papers that “ambition must be made to counteract ambition” to protect democracy appears increasingly distant.

This trend toward expanded executive authority extends well beyond a single administration. President Obama’s 2012 implementation of the Deferred Action for Childhood Arrivals (DACA) program through executive action effectively achieved aspects of the DREAM Act that Congress had not passed. More recently, President Biden’s executive actions to forgive federal student loan debt were struck down by the Supreme Court in Biden v. Nebraska. In response, the Biden administration pursued alternative loan-forgiveness measures through the Saving on a Valuable Education plan and income-driven repayment adjustments. Presidents, regardless of party, push policy goals despite legal constraints.

With constitutional limitations weakened, what can effectively check an empowered executive branch? The answer may lie not in constitutional design or judicial rulings, but in free markets.

The Market as an Independent Check

Unlike other institutions, free markets cannot be intimidated or threatened to produce desired outcomes. They operate without regard for political rhetoric or loyalty, simply aggregating the continuous decisions of millions of interdependent economic agents, consumers, employers, workers, and investors, into prices and other economic indicators. Markets work on large numbers of decentralized decisions, allowing policies to be assessed purely on their economic merits.

While measures like the unemployment rate, consumer price index, interest rates, and GDP may seem abstract, they represent real kitchen-table issues that directly affect people’s lives. These macroeconomic indicators reveal today what eventually will be the tangible consequences of policy decisions. Meanwhile, the stock market acts as an early warning system, providing a clear signal that reflects both the immediate impacts on corporate profits and the expected long-term effects on profit growth. Together, these approaches connect the slower, tangible effects of economic issues with the market’s forward-looking signals, providing a more complete picture of policy impact.

Immediate and Unfiltered Feedback

Voters see the policy effects directly through changes in their 401ks or portfolio values, while companies react by increasing cash balances, delaying hiring, or raising prices due to new tariffs. Even as political rhetoric uses euphemisms like “detoxing” to minimize economic pain or ‘art of the steal’ (a play on Trump’s book title, Art of the Deal) to reframe tariffs as clever strategies to reclaim manufacturing jobs, such spin may sway some political supporters. However, markets don’t buy into it.

For example, between February and March, the S&P 500 lost $5.3 trillion in value—an unmistakable signal that investors reject misleading narratives.   Likewise, a steep 11 percent drop in consumer sentiment—described by one economist as “horrific”, shows genuine public concern about economic conditions. If Trump’s tariffs had helped the economy, asset prices and consumer confidence would have risen. The absence of such positive signals provides a true, clear assessment of policy impact.

Critics might argue that markets aren’t a reliable check on poor policies because they sometimes crash, especially in highly uncertain times. But these crashes don’t mean markets have failed. They work like someone breaking the glass on a fire alarm, signaling that something is seriously wrong. In this way, a market crash forces immediate action and reinforces the market’s role as a crucial check on otherwise-unchecked executive power.

Amplifying Consequences

Policies that weaken fiscal stability have real consequences, including higher inflation, job losses, and declining asset values that impact financial security, from retirement accounts to purchasing power. Rather than simply causing poor outcomes or electoral defeat, these policies trigger market reactions that enforce accountability and even amplify their harm. For example, policies that lead to higher inflation and rising mortgage rates further depress home prices, triggering visceral voter anger.

The bond market, in particular, plays a powerful role in keeping government actions in check. In September 2022, UK Prime Minister Liz Truss’s government introduced a mini budget with major unfunded tax cuts aimed at encouraging economic growth. Instead, this led to a sharp sell-off in the bond market. Government bond yields spiked, and the British pound tumbled. The financial instability forced the Bank of England to step in and purchase government bonds to restore order. The market’s backlash undermined confidence in Truss’s leadership, creating dissent within her party and ultimately forcing her to resign after just 44 days in office.

The Soviet Union’s experience also illustrates this principle. Even in a system that severely restricted economic freedom, economic signals proved more powerful than political dictates. When faced with damaging inflation caused by centralized policies, Soviet authorities attempted to “outlaw” inflation — a futile effort that demonstrated the limits of political power against economic realities.

The Ultimate Accountability Mechanism

The market’s response to policy failures is both punitive and transformative. As poor decisions lead to rising unemployment, inflation, and declining investments, voters bear the true cost of executive overreach. The market’s autonomous feedback loop not only exposes these economic consequences but actively amplifies the harm from bad policies, serving as a stimulus for change. While traditional safeguards remain essential in areas like civil liberties and social policy that do not easily translate into economic signals, the market provides a continuous, impartial check on unchecked executive power.

Even as administrations often claim that their policies generate prosperity, stating for example, that tariffs benefit the nation — political spin cannot alter the market’s verdict. No matter how staunchly allies defend these narratives, economic reality prevails. This feedback forces corrective action when necessary, demonstrating that in a democratic society with functioning markets, the collective judgment of millions stands as a vital counterbalance to unchecked executive power. In this way, free markets represent the ultimate defense against executive overreach, functioning where constitutional checks and conventional political norms have failed.

Last month, a video was trending on social media showing a Canadian woman explaining that she had a 13-month wait for a magnetic resonance imaging (MRI) test to check for a brain tumor.

On X, formerly known as Twitter, community notes popped up to say that the video was misleading. “Priority is decided by physicians, not the province,” wrote one commenter. Another noted that wait times did vary by province.

None of this, however, detracts from the core truths: Canadian health care is not free and it has two prices: the taxes Canadians pay for it and the wait times that make Canadians pay in the form of service rationing.

Canada’s publicly provided health care system actually requires rationing in order to contain costs. Because services are offered at no monetary price, demand exceeds the available supply of doctors, equipment, and facilities. If the different provinces (which operate most health care services) wanted to meet the full demand, each would have to raise taxes significantly to fund services. To keep expenditures down (managing the imbalance from public provision) and thus taxes as well, the system relies on rationing through wait times rather than prices.

The rationing keeps many patients away from care facilities or encourages them to avoid dealing with minor but nevertheless problematic ailments. These costs are not visible in taxes paid for health care, but they are true costs that matter to people.

All this may sound like an economist forcing everything into the “econ box,” but the point has also been acknowledged by key architects of public health care systems themselves. Claude Castonguay, who served as Quebec’s Minister of Health during the expansion of publicly provided care, conceded as much in his self-laudatory autobiography. The reality, he explains, is that eliminating rationing would imply significantly higher costs — costs that politicians are generally unwilling to justify through the necessary tax increases. Multiple government reports also take this as an inseparable feature of public provision — even though they do not say it as candidly as I am saying it here.

To illustrate the magnitude of rationing (and the trend), one can examine the evolution of the median number of weeks between referral by a general practitioner and receipt of treatment from 1993 to 2024. In most provinces (except one), the median wait time in 1993 was less than 12 weeks. Today, all provinces are close or exceed 30 weeks. In two provinces, New Brunswick and Prince Edward Island, the median wait times exceed 69 weeks. For some procedures, such as neurosurgery, the wait time (for all provinces) exceeds 46 weeks.  

Figure 1:

Output image

Estimating the full cost of health care rationing is far from straightforward. The central challenge lies in balancing data reliability with the breadth of conditions considered. While some procedures and ailments are well documented, they represent only a subset of those subject to rationing. For many other conditions, data quality is limited or inconsistent, making comprehensive analysis difficult. As a result, most empirical studies focus narrowly on areas where measurement is more robust, leaving much of the total cost unaccounted for.

In 2008, the Canadian Medical Association (CMA) released a study estimating the economic cost of wait times for four major procedures: total joint replacement, cataract surgery, coronary artery bypass graft (CABG), and MRI scans. For the year 2007, the CMA estimated that the cost of waiting amounted to $14.8 billion (CAD). Relative to the size of the Canadian economy at the time, this represented approximately 1.3 percent of GDP. That study did not include, as one former president of the CMA noted, $4.4 billion in foregone government revenues resulting from reduced economic activity. It also does not include the cost of waiting times for new medications.  

These procedures do not capture the full scope of delays in the system and only a few procedures — and the analysis focused only on an arbitrary definition of “excessive” wait times. In 2013, the Conference Board of Canada found that adding an extra two additional ailments boosted the cost from $14.8 billion to $20.1 billion.

Another study used a similar method, but considered the cost in terms of lost wages and leisure. It arrived at a figure, for 2023, of $10.6 billion or $8,730 per patient waiting.

One study attempted to estimate the cost of rationing in terms of lives lost. This may seem callous, but lives lost means lost productivity — a way to approximate the cost of wait times. One study found that one extra week of delay in the period between meeting with a GP and a surgical procedure increased death rates for female patients by 3 per 100,000 population. Given that the loss of a life is estimated at $6.5 million (CAD), this is not a negligible social cost in terms of mortality.

And all of this for what? One could argue that these wait times come with good care once obtained. That is not true either. 

Adjusting for the age of population, Canada ranks (out of 30):

  • #28 in doctors
  • #24 in care beds
  • #25 in MRI units
  • #26 in CT scanners 

In one comparative study examining care outcomes — such as cancer treatment, patient safety, and procedural success — “Canada performed well on five indicators of clinical quality, but its results on the remaining six were rated as either average or poor.” This is despite, after again adjusting for population age structure, Canada ranking as the highest spender among a group of 30 comparable countries.The reality is that, whatever nuances one wishes to introduce — whether in good faith, pedantically, or simply to troll — the core message of the viral video remains accurate: Canadian health care works well for those who can afford to wait. To which I might add: wait very long.

If you maintain that over time, the United States has been the best country at exemplifying the teachings of Adam Smith, you would get no argument from me.  

Sadly, that imagined crown no longer fits. By one calculation, with President Trump’s new tariffs, the United States “is about to have the highest tariff rate of any advanced economy” with a rate of “around 22 percent — up from 1.5 percent in 2022.”

Smith’s teachings on markets and human nature established the foundation for a free trade policy. It would seem the fate of humanity is to forget timeless truths, endure the consequences, and struggle to recover those truths.  

Timeless principles apply everywhere and always. Principles ensuring human flourishing are mutually beneficial, not zero-sum. Famously, Smith pointed us to the advantages of the “division of labour” and how, under conditions of freedom, our actions lead us to naturally become “mutually the servants of one another,” helping each other thrive. 

We can assume tariff supporters have the best intentions, yet ultimately, intentions don’t matter. In his preface to the 1976 edition of The Road to Serfdom, FA Hayek warned that “unless we mend the principles of our policy, some very unpleasant consequences will follow which most of those who advocate these policies do not want.” 

When we are out of alignment with the principles by which humanity flourishes, there are consequences. The more we are out of alignment, the more severe the consequences. 

If the sirens’ call of protectionism is seducing you, perhaps it is time to review the clear teachings of Adam Smith in The Wealth of Nations. Regarding the outcome of President Trump’s new tariffs, I would bet the nation’s future on Smith’s principles rather than Trump’s passions.  

Let’s begin with a statement of the purpose that drives human activity. Smith writes, “Every man is rich or poor according to the degree in which he can afford to enjoy the necessaries, conveniencies, and amusements of human life.” 

To achieve the wealth we seek, we are almost 100 percent dependent on the efforts of others. Smith pointed out, “After the division of labour has once thoroughly taken place, it is but a very small part of these [necessaries, conveniencies, and amusements] with which a man’s own labour can supply him. The far greater part of them he must derive from the labour of other people.” 

My wife dedicates a lot of time and energy to her vegetable garden. When we factor in her investments, the cost of homegrown food surpasses that bought at a farm stand or supermarket. Her devotion of time and energy is uncoerced — she gains much from gardening — and doesn’t violate Smith’s maxim: “Every prudent master of a family, never [attempts] to make at home what it will cost him more to make than to buy.” 

Smith gives us clear examples: “The tailor does not attempt to make his own shoes, but buys them of the shoemaker. The shoemaker does not attempt to make his own clothes, but employs a tailor.” 

Smith then generalizes the principle: “What is prudence in the conduct of every private family, can scarce be folly in that of a great kingdom.”

It is not merely domestic production that Smith referred to: “If a foreign country can supply us with a commodity cheaper than we ourselves can make it, better buy it of them with some part of the produce of our own industry, employed in a way in which we have some advantage.” 

Smith used the example of the folly of growing wine in Scotland: “By means of glasses, hotbeds, and hotwalls, very good grapes can be raised in Scotland, and very good wine too can be made of them, at about thirty times the expense for which at least equally good can be brought from foreign countries.”  

And then Smith asked the pertinent question: “Would it be a reasonable law to prohibit the importation of all foreign wines, merely to encourage the making of claret and Burgundy in Scotland?”

He soundly answered no: “There would be a manifest absurdity in turning towards any employment thirty times more of the capital and industry of the country than would be necessary to purchase from foreign countries an equal quantity of the commodities wanted.”

Consider President Trump’s assertion that these tariffs are retaliatory measures to protect America from unfair trade practices. The President’s calculations are dubious, but let’s make the best case for his policies and suppose his calculations are correct. 

Smith allows, “There may be good policy in retaliations of this kind, when there is a probability that they will procure the repeal of the high duties or prohibitions complained of.”

But what is the probability of that happening? Smith cautions that the likelihood of repeal depends on “the skill of that insidious and crafty animal, vulgarly called a statesman or politician.” 

Skeptical of success, Smith argued that politicians “are directed by the momentary fluctuations of affairs.”

He added, “When there is no probability that any such repeal can be procured, it seems a bad method of compensating the injury done to certain classes of our people, to do another injury ourselves, not only to those classes, but to almost all the other classes of them.”  

Those who love the well-being of this country hope the President is a free trader at heart and hope Trump will negotiate regional and then worldwide tariff reductions quickly. Smith wouldn’t bet on that.

In The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith cautioned against “The man of system, … very wise in his own conceit,… [who] seems to imagine that he can arrange the different members of a great society with as much ease as the hand arranges the different pieces upon a chess-board.”

And what about the moral side of the equation? Let’s set aside the charged issue of trade with China. Trump has imposed a 49 percent tariff on Cambodia and a 46 percent tariff on Vietnam. Both countries export a considerable amount of shoes and clothing to America. The higher prices will hurt American consumers, and Cambodia and Vietnam will suffer devastating economic consequences.

Does the President think Cambodian and Vietnamese workers have ripped us off? Or is it the factory owners? The Vietnamese government, for example, doesn’t trade with the American government. American businesses voluntarily trade with Cambodian and Vietnamese companies (often owned by foreign investors).

Free trade arguments will not sway the economically illiterate. Their faith in President Trump overshadows their understanding of Adam Smith’s economics and dulls their moral compass. We’re told that America’s interests must come first. Smith would say yes, let’s make America great, but trade, not tariffs, is a pathway to progress.

Though economics is called by some a dismal science, a truly dismal philosophy is that the world is a win-lose proposition, where one must beat others or be beaten. 

In his The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Smith explained why our moral sense, rooted in sympathy for others, promotes mutual respect.

Smith began Moral Sentiments with this optimistic moral observation: “How selfish soever man may be supposed, there are evidently some principles in his nature, which interest him in the fortune of others, and render their happiness necessary to him, though he derives nothing from it except the pleasure of seeing it.” 

Prosperity in Cambodia and Vietnam should matter to Americans because of our shared humanity and also because it benefits us economically. Americans, Cambodians, and Vietnamese march in the same band, no different than Kansans and Iowans. We ignore Smith’s timeless teachings at the risk of our economic and moral well-being.