On May 22, Donald Trump celebrated the House’s passage of HR1 , proclaiming
THE ONE, BIG, BEAUTIFUL BILL has PASSED the House of Representatives! This is arguably the most significant piece of Legislation that will ever be signed in the History of our Country!
Incredibly, the actual formal name of the bill, in the legislation itself, is “The One Big Beautiful Bill” Act. Unsurprisingly, the bill is now often called the “OBBBA.”
It’s hard to know if “Big Beautiful Bill,” a vague description with a positive valence, is better or worse than the “Inflation Reduction Act,” which was cynically named to be the opposite of its intended and obvious effects. While the bill is big, the question of whether it is beautiful is more contentious.
There are many things that might be said about the OBBBA. Given the problems of D.A.F.T. policy, this bill seems irresponsible. As David Hebert recently said, a focus on spending cuts, even if they were real, cannot be enough. It will take real spending cuts to solve the deficit problem, and OBBBA definitely does not come close to cutting spending.
I want to look at a different part of the OBBBA, the proposal to expand the state-and-local tax (“SALT”) deductions. Here is what the House version of the Bill actually says about SALT:
[Internal Revenue Code sec. 275] is amended so that no individual deduction shall be allowed for…any specified taxes that exceed—
(I) $20,200, for married filing separately, or
(II) $40,400, for any other taxpayer
There are some details that involve a reduction in these caps for taxpayers with incomes much over $500,000, and also indexing the caps for inflation, but the above captures the gist of the proposed change.
In broad terms, the mechanics of SALT deductions work like business expenses, and in fact deducting taxes from profits makes sense for businesses. But allowing the deduction of tax payments for individuals is actually quite a different matter, because instead of subsidizing people the deductions subsidize states, in effect rewarding those states that impose excessive tax burdens on their citizens.
Consider the jurisdictions where the SALT deduction has the biggest impact: California, Connecticut, District of Columbia, Maryland, Massachusetts, New Jersey, and New York. Biggest impact means that these states either have both a high proportion of itemizers and large average SALT deductions (and probably both).
To give a basis for comparison, let’s look at the top “big tax” states, which are listed in the following table.
Top 10 States by Income Tax Rates and Corresponding Sales Tax
Rank
State
Income Tax (Top Marginal)
Sales Tax (Avg Combined)
1
New York
14.78%
8.875%
2
Oregon
14.69%
(no sales tax)
3
California
14.40%
~8.85%
4
New Jersey
11.75%
6.625%
5
Hawaii
11.00%
4.5%
6
Minnesota
9.85%
~8.375%
7
Massachusetts
9.00%
6.25%
8
Maryland
8.95%
6%
9
Vermont
8.75%
~7%
10
Maine
7.15%
5.5%
Now, we live in a “federal” system, meaning that the tax and regulatory policies of states are disciplined by the ability of citizens to “exit” if a state tries to take, or control, too much. The highlighted states had net out-migration of US citizens (though not always of foreign immigrants) over the period 2010-2020. Tax policy is not the only reason, but it is a factor.
The problem is that the SALT deduction substantially mitigates the incentives states have to adopt responsible tax policies. In fact, SALT imposes a “cross-subsidy,” where the low-tax states have to make up the difference in tax revenues at the federal level. Consider an example: Suppose State A has a 12 percent income tax, State B has no income tax. Citizens in both states pay 30 percent (in our example) federal income taxes.
Take, for example, a household earning $100k per year in each state. The citizen of B pays $30k in federal income taxes, and no state income taxes.
But the citizen of A pays $12k in state income taxes, and that tax is deducted from their taxable income! As a result, the citizen of state A pays only $26.4k of federal income tax.
In effect, the citizens of B are being forced to pay extra federal tax, to make up for the profligacy of the state government of A, a state where citizens of B have no vote, and may never even have visited!
Worse, the SALT deduction benefits only the very highest earners, and those who itemize their deductions, leaving out the many poorer citizens who might benefit from the deduction. According to the Tax Policy Center, more than 90 percent of the benefits of the uncapped SALT deduction went to households earning over $100,000.
The states that benefit most from SALT deductions, and which would benefit most from the OBBBA amendments to the policy, have acted badly and are only getting worse. David Ditch, an analyst at EPIC, notes that California, perhaps the worst overall offender, has chosen a path that cannot be sustained, or justified. In 2000, California’s state budget was already 26 percent larger than the combined budgets of Texas and Florida, despite those two states having three million more residents.
Since then, the population gap has widened: Texas and Florida now have 15 million more people than California. Yet California’s budget has grown to be 81 percent larger than the combined budgets of those two faster-growing states.
California, all by itself, shows the consequences of how badly SALT deductions work to constrain poor tax policy. It is plausible to conjecture that a substantial part of the reason that Florida and Texas are growing faster is that they have more sensible tax policies.
One can be a fan of state’s rights, and the ability of state governments to have different tax and spending regimes, since citizens are free to move among states and choose the configuration that they want. But the proposed OBBBA amendments go in the wrong direction, quadrupling the SALT deduction. The result would be that citizens in Texas and California will pay substantially higher federal tax rates than Californians, and for no reason other than the fact that Californians are being protected from the full consequences of their irresponsible policy choices.
The late Peter Drucker is considered the father of modern management theory. Born in Vienna, he was a young lecturer at Frankfurt University early in Hitler’s regime. In his book Adventures of a Bystander (retold in Life in the Third Reich), Drucker recounts the initial Nazi-controlled faculty meeting at Frankfurt University, which occurred shortly after Hitler’s rise to power in 1933.
Drucker sets the stage: “Frankfurt had a science faculty distinguished both by its scholarship and by its liberal convictions; and outstanding among the Frankfurt scientists was a biochemist–physiologist of Nobel-Prize calibre and impeccable liberal credentials.”
The Nazi commissar wasted no time taking charge of the meeting. Drucker remembers the commissar telling the faculty, “Jews would be forbidden to enter university premises and would be dismissed without salary on March 15.”
“Despite the Nazis’ loud anti-Semitism,” the faculty didn’t see that coming.
Vulgarity and threats followed as the commissar “pointed his finger at one department chairman after another and said, ‘You either do what I tell you or we’ll put you into a concentration camp.’”
Silence filled the room; everyone waited for the distinguished scientist and “great liberal” to speak. The liberal rose and said, “Very interesting, Mr Commissar, and in some respects very illuminating: but one point I didn’t get too clearly. Will there be more money for research in physiology?”
The faculty were easily bought with “the commissar assuring the scholars that indeed there would be plenty of money for ‘racially pure science.’” The faculty did not push back. (Anyone who’s spent time in academia shouldn’t be surprised.)
A few men of courage walked “out with their Jewish colleagues, but most kept a safe distance from these men who only a few hours earlier had been their close friends.”
In a state of shock, Drucker resolved to depart Germany within 48 hours, which he did.
Similar events occurred throughout Germany. In his book Hitler’s True Believers, Robert Gellately explains that before 1933, National Socialism already had footholds at the universities.
Shortly after Peter Drucker left Nazi Germany, Gellately reported, “The distinguished physicist Max Planck was asked whether he would like to get involved in a meeting to discuss the treatment of Jewish professors.” Planck answered “meekly that if thirty professors did that, there would be [in Planck’s words] ‘150 people ready to declare their solidarity with Hitler tomorrow, because they want to have those jobs.’” (Planck was not a Jew.)
Gellately concluded, “In their silence the establishment professoriate might be viewed as coming close to complicity.”
The long-term ruin of their lives was the price German professors paid for short-term benefits.
Envy and greed — the desire to get something for nothing — are common human emotions. In Law, Legislation and Liberty, Volume 3, FA Hayek explained, “The morals which maintain the open society do not serve to gratify human emotions.”
Hayek instructs, “Civilization largely rests on the fact that the individuals have learnt to restrain their desires for particular objects and to submit to generally recognized rules of just conduct.”
It was not just academics who lined up to fill jobs held by Jews. Gellately reported that “Medical doctors rushed to join the Nazi Party” as they “coveted the positions of Jewish physicians.”
In his book The Third Reich: A History of Nazi Germany Thomas Childers reported, “All ‘non Aryans’ [were] dismissed immediately from the national, state, and municipal civil service. Jews were no longer allowed to serve as schoolteachers, university professors, judges, or in any other government post.”
In short, before murdering Jews, Nazi Germany ran a proto-DEI program for “Aryans.”
Today, Harvard University, which has been accused of condoning antisemitic activity, has a Jewish student body of less than 5 percent. During the 1970s, as much as 25 percent of Harvard students were Jewish. Modern “progressive” DEI programs have a goal similar to Nazi DEI programs — reduce or eliminate Jewish and white representation from institutions and corporations.
According to Saul Friedländer’s The Years of Extermination, Nazi decrees did not push far beyond what the public would accept. Sentiments of the public and influential entities, such as the church and industry, were considered. Friedländer reported,
Not one social group, not one religious community, not one scholarly institution or professional association in Germany and throughout Europe declared its solidarity with the Jews… many power groups were directly involved in the expropriation of the Jews and eager, be it out of greed, for their wholesale disappearance.”
Sadly, Friedländer concluded, “Naziand related anti-Jewish policies could unfold to their most extreme levels without the interference of any major countervailing interests.”
Government coercion is required for antisemitism to reach its most damaging consequences.
Childers tells the story of an April 1, 1933, government-supported boycott of Jewish businesses: “Storm Troopers stationed themselves in front of Jewish shops, department stores, and professional offices, menacing anyone who wanted to go inside. They carried anti-Semitic placards and scrawled slogans on Jewish shop windows.”
“Germans, defend yourselves. Don’t buy from Jews,” was among the slogans.
The Nazis, however, were not pleased with the public response to the boycott. Childers reported, “Many customers ignored the boycott, brushing past the SA pickets to shop at Jewish businesses and department stores.” Worse for the Nazis, “some shoppers had even tried to enter a Jewish business by force,” and other “customers had been feverishly stocking up on merchandise from Jewish shops for days prior to the boycott.”
The next day, the boycott was canceled. The Nazis waited to implement more extreme actions.
Childers also reported that in 1933, Germans “still visited their Jewish doctors and lawyers.” Not long after, new edicts resulted in Jewish doctors being allowed to treat only other Jews, a situation which led Jewish doctors to flee Germany or eventually be murdered in concentration camps.
At first, the bonds of commerce proved stronger than Nazi hatred. Yet the Nazis worked tirelessly to eliminate commercial connections — the bonds on which our lives depend.
In his An Enquiry Concerning the Principles of Morals David Hume wrote, “It has often been asserted, that, as every man has a strong connexion with society, and perceives the impossibility of his solitary subsistence, he becomes, on that account, favourable to all those habits or principles, which promote order in society.”
Hume called such an order an “inestimable blessing” that must be maintained by “the practice of justice and humanity, by which alone the social confederacy can be maintained, and every man reap the fruits of mutual protection and assistance.”
In his seminal A Treatise of Human Nature, Hume explained, “The passions [human emotions] are so contagious, that they pass with the greatest facility from one person to another.”
Arguably, a human passion at the root of social disruption is the insatiable desire to be free from necessity. In The Road to Serfdom, Hayek described this desire as a yearning for “release from the compulsion of the circumstances which inevitably limit the range of choice of all of us.”
Our choice is to support politicians who promise the impossible freedom from scarcity, or those who promise freedom from coercion, which is possible. Freedom from coercion comes with all the choices and responsibilities we bear under a liberal form of government.
Liberty cuts off the coercive power of government to “satisfy our wishes,” as Hayek wrote in The Constitution of Liberty. Human nature causes some wish to use illiberal means to obtain what they desire. Liberty, freedom from coercion, offers the most effective solution to the dangerous escalation of antisemitism.
According to Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell, the Fed’s flexible average inflation targeting (FAIT) framework played no role in the post-pandemic inflation surge, and officials acted swiftly once inflation proved demand-driven. This paper shows Powell’s claims are not supported by the evidence. The rise in the price level was driven by a surge in nominal spending. Fed officials were slow to recognize the problem and waited six months after acknowledging it to meaningfully tighten policy. Far from irrelevant, FAIT helps explain why the price level remains elevated today. The paper concludes by evaluating alternative frameworks and arguing that the Fed should adopt either a nominal spending target or a symmetrical average inflation target.
Key Points
Post-pandemic inflation was demand-driven — a result of monetary policy not supply constraints, “greedflation,” or fiscal policy. The persistent rise in the price level was not an exogenous shock, but the result of excessive monetary accommodation that fueled a sharp surge in spending. Contrary to some popular views and remarks by Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell, supply constraints, corporate “greed,” and fiscal policy cannot explain the magnitude, timing, or duration of the inflation.
The Fed misdiagnosed the post-pandemic inflation problem and responded too slowly. Throughout 2021, Fed officials continued to view inflation as transitory and supply-driven, even as evidence to the contrary mounted. They delayed tightening until March 2022 and proceeded cautiously thereafter, allowing inflation to overshoot their own projections — which were already well above the Fed’s stated two-percent objective.
Flexible average inflation targeting (FAIT) contributed to the problem. FAIT, the Fed’s monetary policy framework adopted in 2020, encouraged the Fed to tolerate above-target inflation in order to make up for past inflation undershoots, but offered no mechanism to offset overshoots. This asymmetry virtually guaranteed tolerance of higher inflation and a permanent rise in the price level — and undermined the Fed’s credibility.
The Fed’s FAIT framework weakens long-run price stability. By failing to stabilize the price level or anchor inflation expectations around a predictable path, the FAIT framework increases the risks of long-term contracting and erodes confidence in the Fed’s ability to deliver monetary stability.
Reforming the framework is essential to ensure price stability. The paper evaluates four alternatives and recommends nominal spending targeting as the best option for achieving price stability and improving communication. A symmetric average inflation target is proposed as a viable second-best.
1. Investigating the Fed’s Targeting Framework
At a January 2025 press conference, Federal Reserve Chair Jerome Powell (2025) claimed that the Fed’s flexible average inflation targeting (FAIT) framework did not contribute to the post-pandemic inflation surge. As he put it:
There was nothing moderate about the overshoot. It was an exogenous event. It was the pandemic and it happened and, you know, our framework permitted us to act quite vigorously. And we did, once we decided that that’s what we should do. The framework had really nothing to do with the decision to — we looked at the inflation as — as transitory and — right up to the point where the data turned against that. [W]hen the data turned against that in late ‘21, we changed our — our view and we raised rates a lot. And here we are at 4.1 percent unemployment and inflation way down. But the framework was more irrelevant than anything else — that part of it was irrelevant. The rest of the framework worked just fine as — as we used it — as it supported what we did to bring inflation down.
According to Powell, the temporary rise in inflation was beyond the Fed’s control.[1] He argued that the framework did not inhibit the Fed’s response; on the contrary, it supported the Fed’s efforts to rein in inflation. In Powell’s account, the Fed responded appropriately and aggressively as soon as the data indicated that inflation was demand-driven. This paper challenges that account.
The following section argues that the rise in inflation (and, consequently, the rise in the price level) was not exogenous, but was driven by excessively loose monetary policy, which fueled a surge in nominal spending. Although Powell is unclear about what he means by “exogenous,” his explanation echoes several popular narratives that attribute the post-pandemic inflation to external factors — such as supply constraints, greedflation, and expansionary fiscal policy.[2] None of these explanations withstands scrutiny. After evaluating each in turn, the evidence overwhelmingly points to a demand-driven inflation surge caused by monetary accommodation (keeping interest rates low, increasing the money supply, or both).
As discussed in Section 3, the underlying problem was the Fed’s delayed response to a positive aggregate demand shock of its own making. The Fed’s December 2021 projections make clear that officials expected inflation to fall in the final months of 2021 without any change in the stance of monetary policy, suggesting they continued to view inflation as transitory — even though Powell had retired the term weeks earlier. In short, Fed officials viewed inflation as supply driven as late as December 2021 and, as a result, failed to adjust policy accordingly. This distinction matters: if the post-pandemic inflation surge was primarily supply-driven, there was little the Fed could have done to reduce it without causing other problems; if, on the other hand, it was demand-driven, circumstances called for tighter monetary policy to rein in excessive spending in the economy.
Section 4 shows that, contrary to Powell’s claim, the Fed did not change its policy stance when the data turned against the transitory supply-side story in the back half of 2021. The Fed did not begin raising the federal funds rate target until March 2022 — three months after Fed officials publicly acknowledged the demand-side nature of inflation. Even then, officials proceeded cautiously, despite inflation surging past their projections during the early months of 2022. Indeed, it was not until July 2022 that Fed officials finally took more aggressive action.
Section 5 argues that FAIT is far from “irrelevant” to understanding the Fed’s delayed response to the post-pandemic inflation surge. Its adoption in August 2020 marked a clear shift from the Fed’s previous inflation-targeting regime, formally introduced in 2012. Whereas the earlier framework emphasized a symmetric two-percent inflation target (a stance the Fed clarified in 2016), FAIT introduced an explicit commitment to make up for past shortfalls, allowing inflation to moderately overshoot the target following periods of undershooting.[3] In practice, however, the Fed’s implementation of FAIT was asymmetric: it invoked the framework to justify continued accommodation in 2021 but made no effort to offset subsequent above-target inflation with below-target inflation.[4] This asymmetry inhibited the Fed’s response in two ways. First, it gave officials a rationale for delaying tightening, since moderate overshooting was consistent with the framework’s backward-looking logic. Second, it discouraged the pursuit of a superior objective — stabilizing the price level — by making no provision for correcting upward drift once inflation took hold.
Finally, Section 6 discusses several proposed alternatives and revisions to the current framework. Some of these alternatives — such as symmetric average inflation targeting and nominal GDP level targeting — appear more likely to promote price stability and reduce the risk of similar failures in the future. These options are offered to provide Fed officials and others interested in monetary policy with a fresh perspective on the current framework and suggest ways it might be revised to strengthen monetary stability.[5]
2. What Drove the Post-Pandemic Rise in the Price Level?
The price level has risen substantially since January 2020 (see Figure 1). To understand why — and to assess Chair Powell’s claim that this rise was “exogenous” — it is helpful to examine how the personal consumption expenditures (PCE) price index, the Fed’s preferred measure of inflation, evolved during this period. The paper begins by reviewing the trajectory of the price level, then evaluates three popular, but ultimately unconvincing, explanations for the post-pandemic inflation surge, and finally presents a more compelling alternative: a surge in nominal spending fueled by overly accommodative monetary policy.
2.1. The Trajectory of the Price Level: 2020–2024
Figure 1 plots both headline and core personal consumption expenditures (PCE) indices from January 2020 alongside the Fed’s two-percent target growth path, offering a clear view of when — and by how much — the price level diverged from the Fed’s target. As the figure makes clear, both headline and core PCE inflation initially fell below the Fed’s target, but the decline was brief. By March 2021, the price level had fully returned to the target path, and in the months that followed, surged past it.
Figure 1: Headline and Core PCE Price Indices
Between January 2020 and September 2021, annual headline and core PCE inflation averaged 3.1 and 2.9 percent, respectively — but over the next nine months, they accelerated sharply, averaging 7.7 and 5.6 percent.[6] Inflation began to moderate after mid-2022. Headline PCE inflation averaged 3.2 percent between June 2022 and June 2023, and for 2024, it averaged 2.5 percent. Over the same periods, core PCE inflation averaged 4.3 and 2.8 percent, respectively.
Nonetheless, by December 2024, the headline PCE price index was 8.4 percentage points above where it would have been had the Fed consistently met its two-percent inflation target. While inflation rates have come down from their 40-year highs, the price level remains permanently elevated relative to its target path. What caused the price level to diverge so persistently from the Fed’s target?
2.2. Three Unsatisfying Explanations
Powell’s remarks suggest that he and other Fed officials view the rise in the price level as outside their control. Consider three popular but ultimately unconvincing explanations for the inflation surge — corporate greed, expansionary fiscal policy, and supply constraints — all of which could plausibly align with Powell’s description of the post-pandemic surge as “exogenous.” To be clear, this is not to suggest that these factors played no role in the rise in the price level; rather, none of these explanations accounts for the timing, magnitude, and persistence of the inflation surge, indicating that some other explanation is necessary.
2.2.1. Problems with the “Greedflation” Explanation
As the price level began to rise following the pandemic, many commentators on the political left attributed the surge in inflation to rising corporate profits, arguing that firms exploited supply disruptions and strong demand to increase prices well beyond their cost increases. Sen. Elizabeth Warren (D-MA), for example, tweeted in April 2022, “Corporations have figured out they can use inflation as cover to not only pass along their own increased costs to consumers, but also to price gouge to boost their profit margins.” Echoing this sentiment, former Sen. Sherrod Brown (D-OH) remarked in 2023 that “corporate executives […] pretend they’re making ‘tough choices’ about prices while reporting record profit increases quarter after quarter” and suggested that “this profiteering” was “one of the biggest drivers of inflation.”
While it may be tempting to dismiss these comments as mere political rhetoric, some economists have developed more formal versions of the greedflation view. Lorenzoni and Werning (2023), for example, argue that inflation arises from conflict: different economic agents have incompatible objectives over relative prices, and each exercises only partial or intermittent control over the prices they set. In their staggered-pricing model, each agent raises prices whenever it has the opportunity. The result is that even though relative prices remain unchanged, the cumulative price increases driven by this conflict generate a “general and sustained inflation in all prices.”[7]
Weber and Wasner (2023) offer another version of this argument. When an external shock causes input costs to rise, they contend, firms with market power can effectively collude to raise their prices.[8] Given that “all firms want to protect their profit margins and know that the other firms pursue the same goal,” Weber and Wasner maintain, “they can increase prices, relying on other firms following suit.” Moreover, if bottlenecks create temporary market power, they argue, firms can “hike prices not only to protect but to increase profits.” In other words, when temporary bottlenecks create additional market power, firms might raise their markups — not merely passing on higher input costs, but increasing profits as well.
The greedflation explanation provides incumbent politicians with a convenient scapegoat, so it is no surprise that they prefer it to other, more conventional explanations. There are, however, several problems with this view. For one, it is inconsistent with basic price theory (Hendrickson 2024). Firms cannot raise prices without risking a loss of customers. Higher input costs reduce profit margins. It follows that a rise in a firm’s markup implies one of three things. First, the firm may have initially set its price too low and later corrected it. Second, it may have raised its price too high and failed to make some profitable sales. Third, it may have experienced an increase in demand, allowing it to charge more without losing customers. The first two cases imply that firms were not maximizing profits before the pandemic, which, while possible, seems unlikely. In the third case, the higher demand — not greed — explains the rise in markups.[9]
Another problem with this view is that it assumes market power operates primarily by raising prices through restricting output. While such a mechanism is theoretically plausible, it cannot account for the scale of the post-pandemic inflation without implying an implausibly large contraction in aggregate output growth.[10] Yet even setting that issue aside, the empirical record is inconsistent with the greedflation narrative: output was rising alongside inflation, not falling, during the period in question, which suggests that the observed rise in markups was largely driven by stronger demand, not a rise in market power (See Figure 2).
2.2.2. Problems with the Expansionary Fiscal Policy Explanation
Another common explanation for the post-pandemic inflation — popular on, though not exclusive to, the political right — is that it was driven by expansionary fiscal policy. The federal government sharply increased spending to mitigate the economic fallout of the pandemic and the accompanying restrictions on economic activity. Congress authorized $3.3 trillion across five relief bills passed in 2020 and an additional $1.8 trillion in 2021. As Romer (2021) observes, these measures “ran the gamut from highly useful and appropriate to largely ineffective and wasteful.” Importantly, policymakers made no mention of higher future taxes to offset these expenditures. As a result, aggregate demand rose: households and firms, expecting higher current and future income but no offsetting tax burden, increased their spending. That rise in nominal spending, in turn, put upward pressure on prices.[11]
There is certainly merit to this view. Indeed, the underlying cause of high and hyperinflation is often reckless fiscal policy (Sargent 1982). Nonetheless, some proponents of the fiscal explanation state it in a way that effectively — if not always intentionally — absolves the Fed of any culpability. Expansionary fiscal policy only boosts aggregate demand if the Fed accommodates it.[12] A rise in deficit spending by the federal government pushes interest rates higher. If, in response to higher interest rates, the Fed adjusts its policy rate upward, private spending will decline to offset the rise in public spending, leaving aggregate demand unchanged. The federal government’s fiscal response to the pandemic may have made the Fed’s job more difficult, but it cannot, on its own, explain the rise in inflation that followed; that outcome required monetary accommodation. In this case, rather than raising interest rates to offset the inflationary pressure of higher deficit spending, the Fed held rates near zero and continued large-scale asset purchases — policies that exacerbated, rather than countered, the fiscal stimulus and allowed aggregate demand to surge.
2.2.3. Problems with the Supply-Constraint Explanation
The most plausible interpretation of Powell’s position — and perhaps the most widely accepted explanation for the inflation surge — is that pandemic-induced supply constraints caused the price level to rise. COVID-19 and the resulting restrictions on economic activity sharply curtailed the economy’s ability to produce goods and services in 2020. Although most people returned to work as governments relaxed these restrictions, supply chain disruptions lingered, constraining productive capacity through much of 2021.[13]
The supply-constraint explanation is straightforward: the pandemic reduced aggregate output (measured as real GDP), increasing the scarcity of goods and services, which in turn drove up prices. While theoretically sound — and indeed, quite intuitive — this explanation faces two fundamental problems. First, the timing is off. The sharpest contraction in output occurred in 2020, yet prices rose by less than two percent on average over the first year of the pandemic. Inflation did not begin to rise in earnest until the economy had largely recovered from the initial supply disruptions, as shown in Figure 2, which plots real GDP alongside both the headline and core PCE price indices. When inflation accelerated, output and the price level were rising together — not moving in opposite directions, as one would expect following an adverse supply shock, which tends to reduce the economy’s productive capacity, leading to lower output and higher prices due to increased scarcity.[14]
Figure 2: The Path of Real GDP and the Price Level
The second, and more fundamental, problem with the supply-constraint view is that it cannot account for the permanent rise in the trend price level. In the standard aggregate demand and supply framework, temporary supply shocks cause short-run deviations in output and prices but leave the long-run price level path unchanged. For a given rate of aggregate demand growth, the price level rises temporarily when output falls below potential, but returns to trend as output recovers. By the end of 2024, real GDP had nearly returned to its pre-pandemic growth path, yet the price level remained well above its two-percent target path. In short, the persistence of an elevated price level is inconsistent with a purely supply-driven explanation.
To be sure, supply disruptions likely contributed to the excess inflation observed since the start of 2020. The question is, by how much? Total spending in the economy — i.e., nominal GDP or nominal income — grew at an average annual rate of 4.1 percent over the five-year period preceding the pandemic. During that time, real GDP — inflation-adjusted output — grew by 2.5 percent per year, while inflation — as measured by the GDP deflator — averaged 1.5 percent. From the start of 2020 to the end of 2024, real GDP growth averaged just 2.3 percent. Without a change in total spending, nominal GDP would have continued to grow at its pre-pandemic pace, and the slowdown in real GDP growth would have pushed the average inflation rate up modestly — to around 1.7 percent per year. In reality, however, the GDP deflator grew at an average rate of 3.9 percent over the same period. Hence, only about 10.3 percent of the observed excess inflation can be attributed to reduced output — whether due to pandemic-related supply constraints or, as discussed earlier, rising market power.[15]
2.3. The Real Problem Was Nominal
While the Fed conducted monetary policy reasonably well in 2020 — especially given the peculiarities of the COVID-19 contraction — it was caught off guard when aggregate demand picked up in 2021 (Cachanosky et al. 2021). Nominal GDP, which had grown at an average annual rate of 4.1 percent in the immediate pre-pandemic period, surged by 10.7 percent from 2021:Q1 to 2022:Q1, and by 7.4 percent from 2022:Q1 to 2023:Q1. Although supply constraints contributed to excess inflation, the core problem was that the Fed failed to stabilize aggregate demand (Beckworth and Horan 2025; Luther 2024; Schibuola and Martinez 2021).
To appreciate the scale of the surge in nominal spending, it is useful to compare the actual trajectory of nominal GDP to the Federal Open Market Committee’s (FOMC) implicit pre-pandemic projection. This projection can be inferred by combining the FOMC’s projections of real GDP growth and inflation to estimate the expected path of nominal spending — simply the sum of those two components. In December 2019, the median projection for long-run annual real GDP growth was 1.9 percent and for inflation was two percent, implying a projected long-run nominal GDP growth rate of 3.9 percent per year. Figure 3 plots this projected path alongside the actual path of nominal GDP.
Figure 3: The Path of Nominal GDP and the FOMC’s Implied Projection
As the figure shows, nominal spending surged past the FOMC’s implied projection in early March 2021 and has remained elevated ever since. By the end of 2024, nominal GDP stood 14 percent above the level implied by the FOMC’s December 2019 projection. This divergence underscores the extent to which the Fed allowed aggregate demand to overshoot. It also highlights the central policy failure behind the inflation surge: had the Fed begun tightening in early 2021 — when nominal GDP began rising above its pre-pandemic trend — it might have prevented the persistent rise in the price level.
This surge also helps account for the rise in corporate profits and the fall in unemployment below its “natural rate.” If output prices rise faster than input prices, then an unexpected surge in nominal spending — like the one experienced after the pandemic — will temporarily increase corporate profits.[16] Firms, eager to capture these profits by meeting the rising demand, will hire more workers and thereby drive the unemployment rate lower. These developments — which the greedflation and supply-constraint views struggle to explain — follow naturally from a demand-driven story. Hence, unlike the other explanations of inflation, the focus on nominal spending can account for all the “stylized facts” of the post-pandemic inflation.
Why did the Fed wait so long to tighten despite this surge in nominal spending? As the next section explains, the delay likely stemmed from policymakers’ belief that the inflation was supply-driven. Had they focused on nominal spending rather than inflation, Fed officials would have seen much sooner that monetary policy was off track — and might have avoided the inflationary surge altogether. More importantly, it would have avoided the loss of credibility and real economic distortions associated with such a prolonged and preventable overshoot.
3. The Fed’s Misdiagnosis: Mistaking Demand for Supply
In his remarks at the January 2025 press conference, Chair Powell claimed that the Fed began tightening monetary policy as soon as data indicated that inflation would not come down on its own. As shown, this claim is untrue; the data had turned against the supply-constraint view of inflation months before Powell officially retired the term “transitory” in November 2021. Moreover, as late as December 2021, the Fed’s inflation projections implied that officials still expected inflation to decline without any policy tightening — suggesting that they continued to view inflation as the result of temporary supply constraints, despite mounting evidence to the contrary.
This failure to recognize the demand-driven nature of the problem was evident throughout 2021. FOMC members were slow to recognize the rise in aggregate demand, as reflected in their post-meeting statements in April, June, July, and September of that year. In each case, they described the rise in inflation as “largely reflecting transitory factors” (Bergman and Luther 2022). That characterization is consistent with the view that inflation was due to supply constraints — not excess aggregate demand.
This disconnect is also evident in the FOMC’s 2021 Summary of Economic Projections. Table 1 reports the median FOMC member’s actual and implied inflation projections — i.e., what inflation would have to be in the remaining months to hit the year-end target — along with their projections for the federal funds rate (FFR) (Federal Reserve 2021a, 2021b, 2021c, 2021d, 2022a, 2022b). For each projection round, the annualized PCE inflation rate that had already occurred — from the beginning of the year through the most recent month for which data was available at the time of the projection — is calculated. From this is derived the implied annualized inflation rate for the remaining months of the year — that is, the rate that would be consistent with the median FOMC member’s full-year projection given the inflation already observed.
Table 1: Median FOMC Member’s Actual and Implied PCE Inflation Projections and Federal Funds Rate Projections for 2021 and 2022
Projection Date
Inflation Projection for Current Year
Annualized Inflation Year-to-Date
Implied Annualized Inflation for Remaining Months
Median FFR Projection for Current Year
Median FFR Projection for Following Year
Mar 2021
2.4%
5.1%
2.2%
0.1%
0.1%
Jun 2021
3.4%
5.7%
2.3%
0.1%
0.1%
Sep 2021
4.2%
5.9%
1.9%
0.1%
0.3%
Dec 2021
5.3%
5.8%
2.7%
0.1%
0.9%
Mar 2022
4.3%
6.0%
4.1%
1.9%
2.8%
Jun 2022
5.2%
5.8%
4.3%
3.4%
3.8%
Notes: Annualized inflation year-to-date reflects the change in prices from the beginning of the year in which the projection was made through last month for which PCE data was available at the time of the projection. Implied annualized inflation rate for remaining months is determined by the change in prices required over the months not yet recorded at the time of the projection to achieve the median FOMC member’s projection for the year, given the change in prices that had already been recorded.
In March 2021, with year-to-date inflation averaging 5.1 percent annualized, the median FOMC member projected just 2.4 percent inflation for the full year. That implied they expected inflation to average only 2.2 percent annualized over the remaining months. By June, recorded year-to-date inflation had risen to 5.7 percent, and the median FOMC projection increased to 3.4 percent — but again, this assumed inflation would slow, with an implied annualized rate of just 2.3 percent for the rest of the year. In September, year-to-date inflation averaged 5.9 percent annualized, and the median projection rose to 4.2 percent — implying a sharp deceleration to just 1.9 percent annualized over the final months. In December, year-to-date inflation averaged 5.8 percent annualized, yet the median projection for the year rose only to 5.3 percent — again suggesting that FOMC officials expected a dramatic slowdown in inflation over the final two months despite no change in monetary policy.
Throughout this period, the median projection for the federal funds rate remained unchanged, signaling that FOMC members expected inflation to fall without the need for policy tightening. They could see that supply constraints had largely eased, yet they continued to expect inflation to return to normal on its own. Indeed, the FOMC’s post-meeting statement from November 2021 indicated that officials continued to blame supply constraints for the elevated inflation rates, noting that they were “largely reflecting factors that are expected to be transitory.”
By December, FOMC members appeared to be losing confidence in the supply-disruptions view. The word “transitory” was purged from the post-meeting statement, and Fed officials finally acknowledged the demand-side problem: “Supply and demand imbalances related to the pandemic and the reopening of the economy have continued to contribute to elevated levels of inflation,” they wrote. But they still expected inflation — which had averaged 5.8 percent through October — would fall to an average of 2.7 percent over the remaining two months. Moreover, the FOMC did not immediately raise its policy rate, despite having acknowledged the demand-side problem. Instead, it began tapering asset purchases and signaling that rate hikes would not begin until March 2022.
Despite Powell’s claim to the contrary, the emerging consensus among economists is that the Fed should have recognized the rise in aggregate demand much earlier. By September 2021, the evidence was clear enough that a shift in policy stance was warranted. For example, all eight policy rules evaluated by Papell and Prodan-Boul (2024) recommended raising the federal funds rate by 2021:Q3, if not earlier. Likewise, Eggertsson and Kohn (2023) argue that “from September 2021 onward, it was becoming increasingly clear, at least in retrospect, that the inflation surge was broad based and persistent.”
4. A Slow and Hesitant Policy Response
Chair Powell claims that once Fed officials recognized that inflation was demand-driven, they quickly changed course. Again, however, this statement misses the mark. Although the FOMC acknowledged in December 2021 that inflation was at least partially due to excess aggregate demand, it did not begin raising rates until March 2022 — several months later — and even then proceeded cautiously. Moreover, as inflation continued to exceed the FOMC’s projections during the early months of 2022, officials were slow to accelerate the pace of tightening. In short, not only did Fed officials misdiagnose the nature of the problem — once they recognized it, they were slow to act.
As shown in Table 1, the median FOMC member projected in December 2021 that inflation would reach 5.3 percent for the year. The full range of projections (not shown in the table) was 5.3 to 5.5 percent. At the time, FOMC members had access to PCE data through October 2021 and other indicators — including firsthand observations — through November. Yet they significantly underestimated inflation. In January 2022, the Bureau of Economic Analysis announced that inflation had actually been 5.8 percent in 2021 — above the entire range of projections. That estimate would later be revised up to 6.2 percent.
To illustrate how quickly prices outpaced FOMC projections following their acknowledgment of demand-side pressures in December 2021, consider the price level paths implied by the median FOMC member’s inflation projections in December 2021, March 2022, and June 2022. In each case, the implied price level begins with the most recent month for which data was available at the time of the projection. Figure 4 presents the resulting series.
Figure 4: Personal Consumption Expenditures Price Index and Median FOMC Member’s Implicit Price Level Projections
Notes: Implicit price level projections are based on the median FOMC member’s PCE inflation projections for the following years and the most recent month for which PCE data was available when the projections were made.
PCE data released in December 2021, January 2022, and February 2022 consistently showed that prices were rising much faster than the median FOMC member had projected. Yet the FOMC did not raise its policy rate in January 2022, nor did it call a special meeting to do so in February. It was not until March 2022 — with year-to-date inflation already at 6.0 percent — that the FOMC finally raised the federal funds rate, and then only by 25 basis points. The median FOMC member revised their inflation projection for 2022 from 2.6 percent in December 2021 (not shown in Table 1) to 4.3 percent in March 2022, and their projection for the federal funds rate from 0.9 percent to 1.9 percent. Yet officials did not accelerate the pace of tightening beyond what they had previously indicated.[17]
Similarly, PCE data released in March and April 2022 showed that prices were still rising well above the median FOMC member’s expectations. Yet the FOMC did not call an emergency meeting in April. Instead, it raised the policy rate by 50 basis points in both May and June. In June 2022, the median FOMC member revised their 2022 inflation projection up to 5.2 percent and their federal funds rate projection up to 3.4 percent. But the real federal funds rate remained negative. The Fed had eased off the accelerator — but it had not yet hit the brakes.
The Fed did not get serious about bringing down inflation until July 2022, when it surprised markets with a 75-basis-point rate hike. It then followed up with additional 75-basis-point hikes in September and November, a 50-basis-point hike in December, and 25-basis-point hikes in February, March, May, and July 2023 — at which point the federal funds rate target range had increased to 5.25 to 5.5 percent. Unfortunately, the damage had already been done: the Fed’s slow response to the surge in aggregate demand had pushed the price level well above its pre-pandemic growth path. As the next section explains, the Fed’s asymmetric implementation of the FAIT framework all but guaranteed that such an error would destabilize the price level path.
5. The Role of the FAIT Framework
According to Chair Powell, the FAIT framework did not inhibit the Fed’s response to the post-pandemic inflation. Here, too, Powell is mistaken. The FAIT framework encouraged the Fed to delay tightening monetary policy and prevented the Fed from tightening sufficiently to bring the price level back down to its prior two-percent growth path. The delay meant prices rose higher than they otherwise would have. The inability to return the price level to its prior growth path risked unanchoring expectations from two percent.
Under FAIT, the Fed aims to achieve two percent inflation on average over time — but it does not target inflation symmetrically. Instead, it offsets only periods of below-target inflation. When inflation exceeds two percent, as it did following the pandemic, the Fed merely aims to bring inflation back down to two percent, without compensating for the overshoot. As a result, the price level remains permanently elevated relative to its initial path.
The Fed adopted FAIT to address a specific problem. Following the onset of the Great Recession in 2008, it consistently undershot its two-percent inflation target. Despite multiple rounds of quantitative easing, inflation averaged just 1.5 percent from January 2009 to January 2020.[18] Fed officials worried that persistently low inflation would unanchor expectations and put downward pressure on nominal interest rates. Coupled with slower population and productivity growth — which lower real interest rates — below-target inflation risked pushing nominal rates to the zero lower bound, thereby constraining the Fed’s ability to respond to future downturns.[19] By committing to offset periods of below-target inflation, Fed officials believed the FAIT framework would help anchor expectations at two percent and reduce the likelihood that nominal interest rates would again approach the zero lower bound (Brainard 2020; Clarida 2020; Powell 2020).
Our recent experience with FAIT reveals that Fed officials were only partially right. The framework may help prevent inflation expectations from falling persistently below target, but it does not prevent them from drifting persistently above it. Indeed, if firms and households believe the Fed will make up for below-target inflation but refuse to offset above-target inflation, they will reasonably expect inflation to exceed two percent on average. In short, the “F” in FAIT — which gives Fed officials the flexibility to pursue their inflation target asymmetrically — conflicts with the “A,” which is supposed to imply that inflation will average two percent over time.
One consequence of the FAIT framework is that, despite assertions to the contrary (see, for example, Federal Reserve (2020)), inflation expectations will not be well-anchored at two percent. Firms and households cannot reliably expect that inflation will average two percent on a go-forward basis. As a result, any long-term contracts they enter into will be based on the assumption that inflation will tend to exceed two percent. More troubling, however, is that parties to long-term contracts must account for the possibility that unexpected inflation will lead to permanent wealth transfers (e.g., from lenders to borrowers when fixed payments lose real value). Thus, long-term contracting under FAIT is riskier than it would be under alternative frameworks. To the extent that this greater risk discourages long-term contracting, FAIT may also impede economic growth.
Another consequence of the FAIT framework is that it encourages the Fed to delay tightening monetary policy when necessary. Because the framework permits inflation to run above two percent for a time in order to make up for prior undershoots, officials may hesitate to respond to early signs of rising inflation — especially if recent inflation has averaged below target. In practice, this creates an asymmetry: the Fed is quick to ease when inflation falls short of two percent but slow to tighten when it exceeds the target. This asymmetry was evident in the wake of the pandemic, when officials emphasized past inflation shortfalls to justify continued accommodation, even as nominal spending surged and inflation pressures mounted. In this way, FAIT’s backward-looking nature blunted the Fed’s responsiveness at a critical moment.
Chair Powell may insist that FAIT did not inhibit the Fed, but this claim does not match the data. FAIT not only contributed to the initial rise in the price level, it also offered no mechanism for correcting the price-level drift once inflation took hold.
6. What Should the Fed Do?
If FAIT did not inhibit the Fed’s response, as Chair Powell claims, one might reasonably expect Fed officials to preserve the FAIT framework going forward. Why fix what is not broken? In fact, during the review process, Fed officials have indicated that they will likely remove the asymmetry implied by FAIT. Despite their public statements, Chair Powell and other Fed officials clearly recognize the problems with the FAIT framework discussed above. In any event, the question the Fed now faces is how to revise its framework in light of recent experience.
This section considers four potential revisions to the current framework:
returning to a symmetric inflation target
implementing a symmetric average inflation target
raising the inflation target
transitioning to a nominal spending target
Although the last option may offer the greatest potential benefits, it also presents significant communication challenges. A symmetric average inflation target could achieve many of the same benefits as a nominal spending target, if implemented effectively. By contrast, returning to a symmetric inflation target or raising the inflation target does not represent an obvious improvement over the current framework. Each proposal is reviewed in turn.
6.1. Symmetric Inflation Targeting
Perhaps the least radical revision to the current framework would be to revert to the symmetric inflation target (IT) adopted in 2016. Under IT, the Fed does not attempt to make up for under- or overshoots. Instead, it lets bygones be bygones and aims to deliver two-percent inflation period by period. The framework is symmetric in the sense that over- and undershoots are treated equally, with deviations from the target resulting in random short-run fluctuations around the two-percent path, rather than systematic over- or underperformance.
The main advantage of IT is that it is relatively easy to communicate to the public. The downside is that, if followed strictly, it can constrain the Fed’s ability to conduct countercyclical monetary policy. Consider a sudden negative aggregate demand shock that reduces inflation. If prices are sticky, real output will temporarily fall below its potential. Under IT, the Fed would continue aiming for two-percent inflation going forward, but from a lower price level than households and firms had expected prior to the shock. Since output will remain below potential until expectations and the price level adjust, this approach can result in a sluggish recovery.
Rather than reducing the risk of long-term contracting, IT may make such contracts even riskier than under the current FAIT framework. Although households and firms can reasonably expect inflation to average two percent under IT, the potential for unexpected deviations means that permanent wealth transfers are more likely. Under IT, the Fed does not correct for past errors, so it may (randomly) over- or undershoot its target. By contrast, under FAIT, the Fed commits to making up for periods of below-target inflation, so those entering long-term contracts need only worry about above-target surprises.[20] In short, the range of potential wealth transfers — and, correspondingly, the risk associated with long-term contracting — is likely to be greater under IT.
6.2. Symmetric Average Inflation Targeting
The most straightforward revision to the current framework would be to make the average inflation target symmetrical. Under a symmetric average inflation targeting (AIT) regime, the Fed would aim to achieve two-percent inflation, on average, over time — meaning that officials would offset both over- and undershoots. As under the current FAIT framework, the Fed would allow inflation to exceed two percent temporarily following periods of below-target inflation. Unlike FAIT, however, the Fed would also allow inflation to fall below two percent temporarily following periods of above-target inflation.
This approach offers several advantages over FAIT. Most importantly, by making up for past misses in both directions, a symmetric AIT framework would tend to stabilize the price level over time. This outcome is more consistent with the Fed’s price stability mandate, would help address longstanding concerns about the redistributional effects of price-level shocks, and would better reflect the historical lessons of the Volcker-Greenspan era (Binder 2025; Hetzel 2025) Moreover, it would reduce the risk associated with long-term contracting relative to both IT and FAIT.
To see how AIT would reduce the risk of long-term contracting, consider again the potential outcomes for those entering long-term contracts. Under AIT, the Fed might (randomly) err by delivering above- or below-target inflation. Unlike under the current framework, however, the Fed would then attempt to make up for this error, eventually restoring the price level to its pre-shock expected path. By doing so, the AIT reduces the risk of long-term contracting. In short, under AIT the price level is mean-reverting and, hence, much easier to predict.
Another advantage of AIT is that it may prompt the Fed to act more quickly following aggregate demand shocks. Because AIT requires the Fed to make up for past mistakes, the further the price level deviates from its target growth path, the more aggressively the Fed must respond to bring it back on track. For example, suppose the Fed significantly undershoots its target for an extended period. In that case, it will need to generate inflation that is higher for longer than would have been necessary had officials acted sooner. Given the political unpopularity of sustained inflation, Fed officials might prefer to keep inflation closer to target by remaining vigilant for deviations and correcting them promptly when they occur.
Nonetheless, AIT has at least one important drawback: it permits the Fed to respond to supply shocks.[21] As Selgin (1997) explains, changes in the price level driven by supply shocks convey useful information that enables households and firms to make informed production and consumption decisions. When the Fed offsets such price-level changes, it imposes unnecessary costs — especially on firms — that would otherwise remain unaffected by the shock, since they must now adjust prices to accommodate the Fed’s response.[22]
The Fed might permit a temporary deviation in the price level caused by a supply shock, expecting it to dissipate as real output returns to potential. But AIT does not require such restraint; it permits — and may even encourage — offsetting those deviations, even when doing so is counterproductive.
During the Fed’s most recent framework review — which ultimately produced the current FAIT framework — AIT “garnered the most public attention…and many observers expected it to be the Fed’s new framework” (Beckworth and Horan 2025). Indeed, the prominence of AIT in those discussions likely contributed to the initial confusion about the Fed’s asymmetric implementation of FAIT. In sum, adopting AIT today would represent a modest — though meaningful — shift from the current framework. The public would likely find a symmetric target more intuitive, and Fed officials and journalists have already done much of the work to explain how AIT operates. For these reasons, a transition to AIT would likely be easier to communicate than more radical alternatives.
6.3. Raising the Inflation Target
Some economists, including Jason Furman (2023a), have argued that the Fed should use its upcoming framework review as an opportunity to raise its two-percent inflation target.[23] This revision could be implemented within the current framework, or paired with one of the alternative inflation-targeting frameworks discussed earlier. Furman contends that a higher inflation target would “cushion the economy against severe recessions” and “give the Fed more scope to cut interest rates and thereby stimulate the economy.” He also argues that, since households and firms would incorporate higher expected inflation into wage and debt contracts, there is little reason to worry about its effects on workers and creditors (Furman 2023b).
There are several problems with this argument. First, the claim that higher inflation can cushion downturns relies on the view that workers are unwilling to accept nominal wage cuts (Akerlof, Dickens, and Perry 1996). But as White (2025) explains, this reluctance is not an immutable behavioral fact; it is an institutionally contingent outcome.[24] During the US postbellum period (1865–1896), for example, real output grew at an average annual rate of 3.7 percent while inflation averaged 2.0 percent. It is unclear how higher inflation would have improved economic performance in that context.
Second, Furman’s claim that a higher inflation target would give the Fed more room to cut interest rates is misleading. The zero lower bound on nominal interest rates only constrains policy in a low-inflation environment if the Fed restricts itself to interest rate instruments. As White (2025) notes, however, there is no reason the Fed must do so. For example, it could instead conduct policy by adjusting the monetary base, in which case the zero lower bound would be irrelevant.
Finally, Furman’s claim that higher expected inflation would not harm workers and creditors is mistaken. As White (2025) explains, higher expected inflation increases the cost of holding money balances, reducing the gains from exchange. It also distorts economic decisions by interacting with unindexed taxes on interest income and capital gains.[25] These effects are far from trivial and would ultimately harm both workers and creditors (Feldstein 1997, 1999; Lagos and Wright 2005; Lucas 2000). Fortunately, Fed officials do not appear to be taking this suggestion seriously. During his semiannual testimony to the US Senate Banking Committee, Chair Powell stated, “We think it’s really important that we do stick to a two-percent inflation target and not consider changing it” (The Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress 2023).
6.4. Nominal Spending Targeting
The best option would be for the Fed to abandon inflation targeting altogether and instead adopt a nominal spending target. Under this framework, the Fed adjusts the money supply to offset changes in money demand, thereby ensuring that nominal spending follows a predetermined growth path. Like average inflation targeting (AIT), this approach requires the Fed to make up for periods when nominal spending deviates from its target path, but it differs from AIT by allowing supply shocks to pass through to the price level and inflation rate. A nominal spending target thus behaves like AIT in the case of aggregate demand shocks, but spares the Fed having to decide whether to deviate from its inflation target in response to aggregate supply shocks, which it is ill-equipped to address directly with its existing tools (interest rate changes and asset purchases) that can only influence aggregate demand, not supply. Like AIT, it makes the price level more predictable over longer time horizons.[26]
To be sure, there is a communication challenge associated with moving from FAIT to a nominal spending target. The Fed’s past frameworks have conditioned the public to think in terms of an inflation target of one sort or another. As a result, a nominal spending target may initially seem like a radical departure from the status quo. That said, Binder (2020) argues that nominal spending targeting would ultimately improve central bank communication:
Part of the difficulty of inflation targeting is that many people either do not know what inflation is or understand it very differently than central bankers do. Many people do not understand that higher inflation can be a consequence of higher aggregate demand. On surveys of consumer expectations, for many consumers, reported inflation expectations are really a proxy for their beliefs about the general state of the economy — that is, consumers report higher inflation expectations when economic sentiment is poor.
By allowing “the Fed to frame its policy decisions in terms of income rather than inflation,” a nominal spending target helps alleviate public confusion about the relationship between inflation and real output fluctuations (Binder 2020). It also reduces uncertainty among households and firms about how the Fed will balance the two sides of its dual mandate. In this way, a nominal spending target could significantly improve central bank communication.
Moreover, while a nominal spending target may sound like a dramatic departure from the status quo, it can be implemented using familiar interest rate rules. For example, Orphanides (2025) proposes a natural growth targeting rule, which prescribes how the Fed should set its policy rate based on the projected growth of nominal spending and the “natural” growth rate — defined as the sum of the Fed’s two-percent inflation objective and the estimated growth rate of potential output. Had the Fed followed this rule during and immediately after the pandemic, it would have begun tightening much sooner and prevented the price level from rising as high as it did.
In sum, nominal spending targeting is not only economically sound but institutionally feasible, representing the best option for promoting monetary stability going forward.
7. Conclusion
Contrary to Chair Powell’s claims, the 2020-2024 rise in the price level was not exogenous — it was the result of an aggregate demand shock caused by the Fed itself. Officials failed to recognize the demand-driven nature of the problem, despite mounting evidence. Nor, contrary to Powell’s claim, did they act swiftly to correct course once they realized that monetary policy was far off track. Far from being irrelevant, the FAIT framework helps explain why the price level remains well above its pre-pandemic growth path. In short, FAIT has failed. It does not promote price stability — it enabled the highest inflation in forty years. It does not anchor expectations — it has eroded the Fed’s credibility.
In retrospect, these outcomes are hardly surprising. By focusing narrowly on inflation, FAIT increases the risk of misdiagnosing demand shocks as supply shocks — as the Fed did in 2021. Had officials focused on nominal spending, they would have seen that aggregate demand was rising rapidly — in other words, that households and firms were increasing their spending at a pace well above the corresponding change in the economy’s productive capacity, putting upward pressure on prices, warranting tighter monetary policy. The Fed’s asymmetric approach to FAIT likely contributed to its slow response. If the framework had required officials to make up for above-target inflation, they would have had stronger incentives to act quickly and limit the size of the necessary correction. Instead, the asymmetry virtually guarantees that inflation will exceed two percent on average.
FAIT was designed to address the perceived problem of persistently low inflation following the Great Recession. In that narrow respect, it succeeded: it eliminated low inflation, but at the expense of price stability. What the Fed needs is a robust monetary policy framework capable of responding to a wide range of economic circumstances. Whatever its other merits, FAIT is not up to the task.
To that end, each of four potential revisions to the Fed’s monetary policy framework was evaluated. Of these, two stand out as especially promising. The best option would be for the Fed to adopt a nominal spending target, which would help anchor expectations, avoid inappropriate responses to supply shocks, ensure a timely response to demand shocks, and improve communication with the public. This approach may be difficult to explain initially. A symmetric average inflation target would be a viable second-best option, offering many — though not all — of the benefits of nominal spending targeting. Either alternative would be a clear improvement over the status quo and would likely have produced better monetary policy in recent years.
Getting this history right matters. If Fed officials are to avoid repeating the same mistakes, they must acknowledge their role in driving prices permanently higher. As they review the framework this year, they should bear one thing in mind: either FAIT enabled the price level to rise permanently above its pre-pandemic path, or it failed to prevent it. Either way, it must go.
References
Akerlof, George A., William T. Dickens, and George L. Perry. 1996. “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:1–59.
Alvarez, Santiago, Alberto Cavallo, Alexander MacKay, and Paolo Mengano. 2024. Markups and Cost Pass-through Along the Supply Chain. Social Science Research Network.
Ball, Laurence. 2014. The Case for a Long-Run Inflation Target of Four Percent. Working Paper. WP/14/92. International Monetary Fund.
Beckworth, David, and Patrick J. Horan. 2025. “The Fate of FAIT: Salvaging the Fed’s Framework.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1391–1403.
Bergman, William, and William J. Luther. 2022. “When Did The Fed Change Its Tune?” https://aier.org/article/when-did-the-fed-change-its-tune/.
Binder, Carola. 2020. “NGDP Targeting and the Public Fed Policy.” Cato Journal 40(2):321–42.
Binder, Carola. 2025. “The Rise of Inflation Targeting.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1229–46.
Blanchard, Olivier J., Giovanni Dell’Ariccia, and Paolo Mauro. 2010. Rethinking Macroeconomic Policy. International Monetary Fund.
Blanco, Andrés. 2021. “Optimal Inflation Target in an Economy with Menu Costs and a Zero Lower Bound.” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 13(3):108–41.
Brainard, Lael. 2020. “Bringing the Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy into Alignment with Longer-Run Changes in the Economy.” Presented at the Brookings Institution, September 1, Washington, D.C.
Brown, Sherrod. 2023. “Brown To Powell: Put Workers First in the Fight Against Inflation | U.S. Senator Sherrod Brown of Ohio.” https://www.brown.senate.gov/newsroom/press/release/sherrod-brown-to-powell-put-workers-first-fight-against-inflation.
Cachanosky, Nicolás, Bryan P. Cutsinger, Thomas L. Hogan, William J. Luther, and Alexander W. Salter. 2021. “The Federal Reserve’s Response to the COVID-19 Contraction: An Initial Appraisal.” Southern Economic Journal 87(4):1152–74.
Clarida, Richard H. 2020.“The Federal Reserve’s New Framework: Context and Consequences.” Presented at the Bookings Institution, November 16, Washington, D.C.
Cochrane, John H. 2023. The Fiscal Theory of the Price Level. Princeton University Press.
Cutsinger, Bryan P., and William J. Luther. 2022. “Seigniorage Payments and the Federal Reserve’s New Operating Regime.” Economics Letters 220:110880.
Di Giovanni, Julian, Ṣebnem Kalemli-Özcan, Alvaro Silva, and Muhammed A. Yildirim. 2023. Pandemic-Era Inflation Drivers and Global Spillovers. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Don Kohn. 2023. The Inflation Surge of the 2020s: The Role of Monetary Policy. 87. Brookings Institution.
Federal Reserve. 2020.“2020 Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/review-of-monetary-policy-strategy-tools-and-communications-statement-on-longer-run-goals-monetary-policy-strategy.htm.
Federal Reserve. 2021a. “December 2021: Summary of Economic Projections.”
Federal Reserve. 2021b. “June 2021: Summary of Economic Projections.”
Federal Reserve. 2021c. “March 2021: Summary of Economic Projections.”
Federal Reserve. 2021d. “September 2021: Summary of Economic Projections.”
Federal Reserve. 2022a.“June 2022: Summary of Economic Projections.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcprojtabl20220615.htm.
Federal Reserve. 2022b.“March 2022: Summary of Economic Projections.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/fomcprojtable20220316.htm.
Feldstein, Martin. 1997. “The Costs and Benefits of Going from Low Inflation to Price Stability.” Pp. 123–56 in Reducing inflation: motivation and strategy, edited by C. D. Romer and D. H. Romer. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Feldstein, Martin. 1999. “Capital Income Taxes and the Benefit of Price Stability.” Pp. 9–40 in The costs and benefits of price stability, edited by M. Feldstein. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.
Furman, Jason. 2023a. “The Fed Should Carefully Aim for a Higher Inflation Target.” Wall Street Journal, August 20.
Furman, Jason. 2023b. “Unexpected Inflation Can Lead to Redistribution, Hurting Creditors and Possibly Workers.” https://x.com/jasonfurman/status/1693791191760781471.
Gordon, Robert J. 1996. “Comment on Akerlof et Al.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:60–66.
Grimm, Maximilian, Òscar Jordà, Moritz Schularick, and Alan M. Taylor. 2023. “Loose Monetary Policy and Financial Instability.”
Hendrickson, Josh. 2024.“Price Theory as an Antidote.” https://www.economicforces.xyz/p/price-theory-as-an-antidote.
Hendrickson, Joshua. 2025. “The Case for Nominal GDP Level Targeting.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1404–19.
Hetzel, Robert L. 2025. “Monetarism and Monetary Policy.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1347–71.
Hogan, Thomas L. 2025. “The Failure of Forward Guidance: Lessons from the Pandemic Recovery.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1265–86.
Ireland, Peter N. 2025. “The Devolution of Federal Reserve Monetary Policy Strategy, 2012–24.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1247–64.
Jordan, Jerry L., and William J. Luther. 2022. “Central Bank Independence and the Federal Reserve’s New Operating Regime.” The Quarterly Review of Economics and Finance 84:510–15.
Lagos, Ricardo, and Randall Wright. 2005. “A Unified Framework for Monetary Theory and Policy Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 113(3):463–84.
Lorenzoni, Guido, and Iván Werning. 2023. Inflation Is Conflict. National Bureau of Economic Research.
Lucas, Robert E. 2000. “Inflation and Welfare.” Econometrica 68(2):247–74.
Luther, William J. 2024. “Neutral Nominal Spending and the Nominal Spending Gap.”
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 1996. “Comment on Akerlof et Al.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1:66–70.
Miller, Tracy. 2024. “Fiscal Policy and Inflation Control: Insights from the COVID Economic Response.” Mercatus Policy Brief Series.
Nelson, Bill. 2025. “How the Federal Reserve Got so Huge, and Why and How It Can Shrink.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1287–1322.
Papell, David H., and Ruxandra Prodan-Boul. 2024. Policy Rules and Forward Guidance Following the Covid-19 Recession. Social Science Research Network.
Powell, Jerome. 2020.“New Economic Challenges and the Fed’s Monetary Policy Review.” https://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/powell20200827a.htm.
Powell, Jerome. 2025.“FOMC Press Conference Transcript of January 29, 2025,” January 29, Washington, D.C.
Romer, Christina D. 2021. “The Fiscal Policy Response to the Pandemic.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 89–110.
Rouanet, Louis, and Alexander William Salter. 2025. “Mission Creep at the Federal Reserve.” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1323–46.
Sargent, Thomas J. 1982. “The End of Four Big Inflations.” Pp. 41–98 in Inflation: Causes and Effects, edited by R. E. Hall. University of Chicago Press.
Schibuola, Alexander D., and Andrew B. Martinez. 2021. “The Expectations Gap.”
Selgin, George. 1997. Less than Zero: The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy. London: The Institute of Economic Affairs.
Selgin, George. 2018. Floored!: How a Misguided Fed Experiment Deepened and Prolonged the Great Recession.
The Semiannual Monetary Policy Report to the Congress. 2023.
Warren, Elizabeth. 2022. “One of the Reasons Why Prices Are Up?” https://x.com/SenWarren/status/1520495104380874760.
Weber, Isabella M., and Evan Wasner. 2023. “Sellers’ Inflation, Profits and Conflict: Why Can Large Firms Hike Prices in an Emergency?” Review of Keynesian Economics 11(2):183–213.
White, Lawrence H. 2025. “Should the Federal Reserve Raise Its Inflation Target?” Southern Economic Journal 91(4):1372–90.
[1] Inflation refers to the rate at which the price level is rising. The price level itself is a measure of the average prices of goods and services at a point in time. A temporary rise in inflation means prices are rising faster for a period; a permanent rise in the price level means they remain elevated even after inflation returns to normal, which is essentially what happened over the past few years.
[2] While Chair Powell has not explicitly endorsed the greedflation or fiscal-policy-driven explanations, these views have shaped the broader public discourse around post-pandemic inflation and often inform the interpretation of external or “exogenous” causes. Including them here clarifies the contrast between demand-driven inflation and non-monetary accounts of the inflation surge. Moreover, even if Powell attributes inflation primarily to supply-side factors, those claims rest on the broader premise that inflation stemmed from forces outside the Fed’s control.
[3] The framework was intended to anchor expectations and prevent interest rates from approaching the zero (or, effective) lower bound. Some economists prefer the word “effective,” which recognizes that, due to transaction costs, nominal interest rates might fall to a level slightly below zero.
[4] The asymmetry in the Fed’s new framework was not initially obvious. Its 2020 Statement on Longer-Run Goals and Monetary Policy Strategy (Federal Reserve 2020) explicitly addresses only the case of below-target inflation. But it also replaced the language of “deviations of employment from the Committee’s assessments of its maximum level” with “shortfalls of employment from the Committee’s assessment of its maximum level,” signaling a more one-sided focus.
[5] This effort is part of a broader symposium reviewing the Fed’s framework, including contributions that examine the historical evolution of inflation targeting (Binder 2025; Hetzel 2025), assess the Fed’s implementation of FAIT (Beckworth and Horan 2025; Ireland 2025), and consider alternative rules-based frameworks (Hendrickson 2025; Orphanides 2025; White 2025). The symposium also explores issues of mission creep (Rouanet and Salter 2025), forward guidance (Hogan 2025), and operating regimes (Nelson 2025).
[6] Unless otherwise stated, inflation rates reported herein are calculated as the continuously compounded annualized rate of change in the personal consumption expenditures price index. This approach produces more interpretable and comparable rates across time periods.
[7] Although Lorenzoni and Werning’s conflict-inflation model offers an elegant formalization of how staggered price-setting by different agents can generate sustained inflationary pressures, there is no role for money, monetary policy, or other nominal determinants of the price level. As a result, the model’s notion of “inflation” reflects ongoing relative price adjustments in a purely real environment, raising questions about whether it meaningfully describes the dynamics of inflation as economists typically understand it.
[8] The collusion need not be explicit. “Besides a formal cartel and norms of price leadership,” Weber and Wasner write, “there can be implicit agreements that coordinate price hikes.”
[9] Alvarez et al. (2024) find that total markups were stable over the period. Since a rise in input costs puts downward pressure on markups, one might interpret the evidence as indicating a relative increase in markups following the pandemic. In other words, firms were able to pass on higher costs to consumers without reducing their margins — suggesting stronger demand, not rising greed.
[10] For a given rate of nominal spending growth, there is a one-to-one tradeoff between inflation and real output growth. Hence, for reduced output to explain even one percentage point of inflation, market power would need to have lowered real GDP growth by a full percentage point. That would represent a roughly 50 percent reduction in trend real GDP growth — implausible given the observed recovery. In other words, blaming inflation on falling output due to increased market power would require an unrealistically large collapse in real economic activity — something we simply did not observe.
[11] See Cochrane (2023) for a theoretical account of the fiscal theory of the price level — the view that prices rise when people believe the government will not raise enough future tax revenue to cover its debts.
[12] Many advocates of the fiscal theory of the price level, including Miller (2024), acknowledge that the recent excess inflation resulted from “a combination of monetary and fiscal policy.”
[13] Compounding these challenges, Russia’s invasion of Ukraine in February 2022 further disrupted global supply — especially in energy markets — pushing oil and other commodity prices higher. The invasion was largely unanticipated, however, so its contribution to the observed rise in the price level (much of which happened earlier) is limited.
[14] Unemployment was also falling as inflation accelerated, further undermining the supply-shock explanation.
[15] Di Giovanni et al. (2023) estimate a multi-country, multi-sector New Keynesian model and similarly conclude that a surge in aggregate demand — not adverse supply shocks — was the primary driver of inflation in 2021 and 2022.
[16] Another reason unexpected increases in nominal spending tend to raise measured corporate profits is that the Fed’s remittances to the Treasury — which are likely to rise with excessive monetary stimulus — are recorded as corporate profits in the National Income and Product Accounts.
[17] As Orphanides (2025) explains, rising inflation reduced the real policy rate over this period — passively loosening monetary policy when tighter monetary policy was required.
[18] Selgin (2018) explains how the Fed’s new floor system, adopted in October 2008, prevented the large increase in reserves from restoring the price level. See also: Cutsinger and Luther (2022), Jordan and Luther (2022), and Nelson (2025).
[19] As discussed below, White (2025) notes that the zero lower bound only limits the Fed’s interest rate policy, not its overall ability to influence aggregate demand.
[20] Technically, whether they must worry about below-target inflation depends on the length of the contract, timing of payments, and the speed at which the central bank makes up for undershooting its target. But the general point remains.
[21] As discussed earlier, inflation driven by supply shocks — such as disruptions to production or increases in input costs — is generally outside the Fed’s control. Attempts to counteract these shocks risk imposing unnecessary economic distortions, especially if real output is already constrained.
[22] Moreover, AIT may amplify macroeconomic volatility (Grimm et al. 2023).
[23] Such proposals are not new. See, for example, Blanchard et al. (2010), Ball (2014), and Blanco (2021).
[24] Gordon (1996) and Mankiw (1996) make a similar point.
[25] When taxes are levied on nominal interest income and capital gains rather than inflation-adjusted amounts, higher expected inflation increases the tax burden on savers and investors. This discourages saving and investment, even though the real (inflation-adjusted) return may not have changed.
[26] As Hendrickson (2025) explains, nominal spending targeting replicates a Pareto-optimal competitive monetary equilibrium — that is, an outcome in which no one can be made better off without making someone else worse off.
What would a world ruled by economists look like? Paul Krugman thinks that in such a world, there would be no need for the World Trade Organization, because all countries would understand that trade is mutually beneficial. Regardless of what others did, each country would follow the principles of free trade. And today, we see this idea of economists in power reflected in reality: Mark Carney, an economist who served as the central banker of two G7 countries, is now the prime minister of Canada. Other economists are also rising to power, take Javier Milei in Argentina, for example. This brings us back to an important question: What is the use of economics in a free society?
A world without barriers to trade, entry, and entrepreneurship may seem like a utopian fantasy — until you imagine the right economists in charge. But there’s a problem: not all economists think the same. And beyond that, politics isn’t just about good ideas; it involves interest groups, voter preferences, and post-rationalization. Often, the best policy doesn’t get chosen. But that’s not the core issue.
The real concern is that when experts make decisions for others, experts become rulers, and this sacrifices individual autonomy for expert rule.
Governing with Econometrics
There was an interesting exchange between Mark Carney and former New York governor Mario Cuomo. Carney quoted Cuomo: “You campaign in poetry. You govern in prose.” Then Carney added, “As the assembled media will tell you, I campaigned in prose — so I’m going to govern in econometrics.” To economists and policymakers, this sounds appealing. Why rely on the old-fashioned political process when we can fine-tune the economy and achieve optimal societal outcomes?
But the problem with this way of thinking is that it sees economics as a tool for social engineering rather than for social understanding. In this mindset, markets are only a part of the technician’s toolbox. When markets help achieve policy goals, they are to be left free. But when they don’t deliver ideal outcomes, they must be corrected or intervened in.
That’s not how we should think about markets. Markets are the institutional embodiment of liberty, not a policy tool for achieving perfect outcomes. They create the environment in which unplanned action — what we call innovation — can take place. They are not systems to be engineered, but processes of discovery that should be left alone to do what they do best: create prosperity.
As Deirdre McCloskey and Art Carden put it: “Leave Me Alone and I’ll Make You Rich.”
Experts in a Free Society
But the question remains: What should economists do in a free society?
Roger Koppl offers a helpful framework in his book Expert Failure, showing how experts can exist in a liberal order. He lays out four types of expert-public relationships.
First, when there is a monopoly of experts and experts decide for non-experts, we face the rule of experts — central planning is the prime example.
Second, when we have competing experts, but experts still decide for ordinary people, we get a quasi-rule of experts, such as in school voucher systems.
Third, if there is a monopoly of experts but people decide for themselves, we get expert-dependent choice — priests are a good example. But the fourth option is the one that preserves individual liberty: competitive experts and self-rule, where citizens decide for themselves. This is what Koppl calls self-rule or autonomy.
The idea that experts — including economists — should not run the world is not a critique of expertise itself. It’s about putting experts on equal footing with citizens. In a free society, experts are part of the political process — not above it. In self-rule, people are free to make their own decisions and consult experts when needed to reduce information asymmetry and make better choices.
In this system, both ordinary people and experts learn from experience and bear the costs of their mistakes — something that doesn’t happen under the rule of experts.
From Managerialism to Liberalism
It seems that the managerialist mindset of the post-WWII era is making a comeback — the age of technocrats and experts. The justification is always the same: emergency. Whether it’s global warming or artificial intelligence, we are told that more state power and more expert rule are necessary to solve the problems we face.
This is not how societies solved their greatest challenges over the past 300 years, however. The doubling of living standards and the lifting of billions out of poverty weren’t achieved through central plans written by expert committees. They were the result of the freedom of ordinary people to discover how to improve their condition.
The managerialist mindset makes a fundamental error: it assumes that the means and ends needed to solve social problems are already known, and the only task left is to implement them correctly. But in truth, the relevant data is incomplete, and the answers are not merely technical — they are discovered, not designed. And in this process, centralized planning becomes a barrier, not a solution.
The role of government is not to deliver predefined social outcomes — it is to uphold the rule of law and allow people to decide for themselves, even if the outcomes are not perfect. As Adam Smith put it:
Little else is requisite to carry a state to the highest degree of opulence from the lowest barbarism, but peace, easy taxes, and a tolerable administration of justice; all the rest being brought about by the natural course of things.
The technocratic mindset disagrees. It assumes that if people are free, they may fail to achieve the “optimal” outcomes defined by economists and social scientists, so they must be guided or forced toward perfection.
But this illusion is dangerous. As William Easterly wrote in The Tyranny of Experts: “The technocratic illusion is that poverty results from a shortage of expertise, whereas poverty is really about a shortage of rights.”
When society forgets this, it risks trading freedom for technical control.
Despite being a proud member of the University of Virginia School of Law Class of 1992, I’m an economist, not a lawyer. Yet had I chosen upon receipt of my JD degree to “do law” rather than return to teaching economics, I certainly would have steered clear of constitutional law. Mastering the subtleties of that branch of jurisprudence requires a mind more supple than my own.
Still, one need not be a Randy Barnett, Richard Epstein, or attorney for the indispensable Institute for Justice to grasp some basic concepts of America’s constitutional order. Crucial to this order is the separation of powers, not only between the national government and state governments, but also among the three different branches of the national government.
One clear passage of the Constitution has been in the news lately because of President Trump’s many executive orders imposing (and often delaying) tariffs. The Constitution’s passage is this: “The Congress shall have Power To lay and collect Taxes, Duties, Imposts and Excises.” This passage from Article I, Section 8 is universally and correctly interpreted to give authority to impose tariffs exclusively to Congress. Neither the executive branch nor the judicial branch have tariff-making authority.
For better or worse, however, the courts have long allowed Congress to delegate to the executive branch many of Congress’s legislative powers. The principal impetus for such delegation came in the early twentieth century from ‘Progressives’ who insisted that our increasingly complex modern society renders the Founding Fathers’ worries about the potential abuse of government power quaint and insubstantial beside the purported need for a government that can act quickly and decisively. And an executive branch in charge of one person can act more quickly and decisively than can a two-house legislature in charge of several hundred persons.
And so among those of its powers that Congress has delegated to the executive branch is the “Power to lay and collect … Duties” (that is, tariffs). (It must be said that Mr. Trump’s on-again, off-again tariff commands prove that, while the actions of the executive can indeed be quick, they aren’t necessarily decisive.) Such delegation of Congressional authority always requires an enabling statute that declares that a delegation is being made and that spells out the terms of that delegation.
The chief enabling statute that Mr. Trump used to justify his “Liberation Day” tariffs is the 1977 International Emergency Economic Powers Act (IEEPA), which, as described by the Congressional Research Service, “provides the President broad authority to regulate a variety of economic transactions following a declaration of national emergency.”
I’m incompetent to discuss whether or not this statute, despite making no mention of tariffs, nevertheless authorizes the president to impose tariffs. Some celebrated legal scholars insist that it does not so authorize; others insist that it does. I want instead to emphasize just how — to describe the matter as clinically as possible — preposterous is the alleged “emergency” that Mr. Trump declared as justification of his “Liberation Day” tariffs. According to the April 2 Executive Order, the emergency that justifies these tariffs are persistent American trade deficits. But not just persistent trade deficits; persistent “goods trade deficits.” But further, not just persistent “goods trade deficits”; persistent “goods trade deficits” with individual countries.
According to Mr. Trump, America now confronts an emergency in the form of bilateral “goods trade deficits” with many of the different individual countries with which it trades. The implication is that this emergency will end only if and when the following outcome is achieved: the value of goods — tangible things — that we Americans export each year to Algeria is at least as great as is the value of goods that we import each year from Algeria, and the value of goods that we Americans export each year to Angola is at least as great as is the value of goods that we import each year from Angola, and the value of goods that we Americans export each year to Bangladesh is at least as great as is the value of goods that we import each year from Bangladesh, and so on for every individual country, down to Zimbabwe, with which we Americans conduct trade.
This allegation of “national emergency” is nonsense, not on mere stilts, but atop a rocket taller than Everest and blasting off at Mach 13,000 for the deepest regions of outer space.
The concept of trade deficits is economically meaningful only when it encompasses trade in both goods and services, and then only for trade with the rest of the world. Neither “goods trade deficits” nor one country’s trade deficit with another country has any economic meaning. And meaning isn’t miraculously imparted to these concepts by pairing them with each other. Instead, this pairing — which Mr. Trump does — only multiplies the nonsense.
US Trade Deficits in Goods and Services With the Rest of the World
At least the concept of trade deficits in goods and services with the rest of the world is economically meaningful. But its meaning is the opposite of what Mr. Trump and other protectionists suppose. American trade deficits arise whenever America is a net recipient of global capital. If foreigners want to invest in America, they cannot spend all of their dollars buying goods and services from America. So as America, relative to other countries, becomes a more attractive place to invest, foreigners spend a smaller portion of their dollars buying American exports, and invest a larger portion of their dollars in American companies. America runs larger trade deficits, but every cent of American trade deficits (more accurately, “current-account deficits”) is a cent of American capital-account surpluses.
Because capital funds the launch of new businesses, the expansion of existing enterprises, and research and development that fuels innovation, the more capital America has, the stronger is our economy. Therefore, US goods and services trade deficits with the rest of the world — that is, US capital-account surpluses with the rest of the world — both evince American economic strength and contribute to it.
(As an aside: Americans continue to benefit from this net inflow of global capital even as the US government becomes more fiscally incontinent. Without the willingness of foreigners to buy US treasuries, the fiscal burden on us Americans of our irresponsible federal government would be even heavier.)
Since America last ran an annual trade surplus, in 1975, industrial production has risen by 154 percent, industrial capacity by 147 percent, inflation-adjusted per-capita GDP by 145 percent, and the average real net worth of an American household by 232 percent. And since 1989 (the earliest year for which I can find reliable data), the real net worth of the average American household in the bottom 50 percent of households has risen by 84 percent.
The above are only a handful of measures by which America’s economy has dramatically improved over the past half-century of persistent annual US trade deficits. Goods and services US trade deficits with the rest of the world, far from being an emergency crying out for government correction, are a blessing for which we Americans should be enormously grateful.
US Goods Trade Deficits…
But what about the “deficits” that so frighten the president: US “goods trade” deficits with individual countries?
Because US goods and services trade deficits with the rest of the world aren’t a problem, logic tells us that the component parts of these deficits aren’t a problem. No more need be said. Yet it’s nevertheless worthwhile to make a few points.
First, there’s nothing economically special about goods production. A dollar’s worth of services such as medical care, software engineering, education, or retailing has the same economic value as does a dollar’s worth of goods such as steel, soybeans, lumber, or automobiles. And because nearly 80 percent of American production today is of services — meaning, most Americans today have a comparative advantage at producing services — it would be bizarre if we Americans did not regularly import more goods than we export.
Put differently, the concept of a “goods trade deficit” makes no more sense than does the concept of a “red-things trade deficit.” A dollar’s worth of roses, beef, merlot, and other red things is the same value as a dollar’s worth of aluminum, maize, chardonnay, and other non-red things. If you understand the absurdity of fretting about a red-things trade deficit, you should understand the equal absurdity of fretting about a tangible-things trade deficit.
… With Individual Countries
What about trade deficits with each individual country? The answer is simple: these ‘deficits’ are irrelevant.
There’s no reason to believe that even in a world of only two countries that trade would necessarily be balanced. (If Country One has a consistently better investment climate than Country Two, Country One could run persistent trade deficits with the rest of the world, namely, Country Two.) But in a world of more than two countries, the notion that trade between any pair of countries will or should be ‘balanced’ is downright ridiculous. This notion makes no more sense than the belief that your dentist will or should buy from you as much as you buy from him.
These two notions — goods trade deficits, and bilateral trade deficits — are each economically absurd. Yet not only does Trump mash together these two absurdities into a single super-absurd concept (goods trade deficits with each individual country), the president asserts that a key expectation of the architects of the post-WWII global trading system was that the US would have balanced trade in goods with every other country. In his Executive order he claims that “the post-war international economic system was based upon three incorrect assumptions,” one of which is that “the United States would not accrue large and persistent goods trade deficits” with individual countries.
This claim is baseless. No person who played any role in designing the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) or its successor, the WTO — and no one who negotiated NAFTA and other pre-Trump trade agreements — ever predicted that as a result of these agreements the US would or should have balanced trade in goods with the rest of the world, and much less that it would or should have balanced trade in goods with each individual country. Indeed, especially because by the mid-twentieth century more than half of US output was of services, had anyone back then dared offer such a prediction, that person would have rightly been dismissed as an economic ignoramus.
No Emergency, No Authority
Whatever the merits of Congressional delegation of tariff-making authority to the president, if that delegation first requires a presidential declaration of an emergency (as the IEEPA does), surely any such emergency declaration must be plausible. Trump’s declaration, alas, is comical, both economically and in its history. Or, rather, his emergency declaration would be comical were it not the basis for actual tariff hikes that will do much damage to America’s and the world’s economy.
The recent weakness in the US dollar has reignited the debate over the durability of the dollar’s dominance in global finance. Over the first half of the year, the Bloomberg Dollar Index has fallen nearly 8.5 percent, marking one of the sharpest declines since the mid-1980s. Yet while this drawdown has fueled widespread commentary about de-dollarization, it is important to distinguish between dollar weakness — a familiar, cyclical phenomenon — and the far more consequential and complex issue of de-dollarization, which concerns the dollar’s standing as the world’s primary reserve currency and medium of international exchange.
Bloomberg Dollar Spot Index & US Dollar Index Spot Rate, 2023- present
(Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)
The current period of dollar weakness is rooted in several overlapping forces. Since Donald Trump’s return to the White House, aggressive trade policies, escalating tariff conflicts, and sharp reversals in longstanding diplomatic and economic norms have unnerved international investors. The dollar index has fallen nearly nine percent since inauguration, the worst such performance since the 1971 Nixon shock, when the US severed the dollar’s convertibility to gold. Bank of America’s fund manager surveys indicate that bearish sentiment toward the dollar is at its highest level since 2006, while foreign appetite for US assets — particularly Treasurys and equities — has declined meaningfully, with foreign ownership of Treasurys falling to 32.9 percent as of late 2024.
Simultaneously, the fiscal position of the United States has worsened considerably. The Trump administration’s substantial tax cuts and growing entitlement obligations are threatening to push deficits to alarming levels, while rising interest costs on government debt threaten long-term fiscal stability. These dynamics are now feeding into market pricing and investor expectations. With global capital increasingly reluctant to finance Washington’s deficits on previous terms, foreign inflows into dollar-denominated assets have moderated. Many foreign investors, particularly from Europe, are in a sustained “buyers’ strike” on US assets, compounding downward pressure on the dollar.
Yearly Growth of Payments via SWIFT in USD, 2020 – present
(Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)
One of the most noteworthy shifts underlying the dollar’s recent slide has been its emerging role as a funding currency for global carry trades. In an environment characterized by stable but modest global growth, subdued volatility, and a widening divergence in interest rates across economies, investors have increasingly sold dollars to finance long positions in higher-yielding emerging market currencies such as the Brazilian real, Mexican peso, Chilean peso, and South African rand. That dynamic introduces a new class of structural dollar sellers, adding both to downward pressure and to heightened volatility. Becoming a favored funding currency — a role long played by the Japanese yen or Swiss franc — reflects declining confidence in the US growth exceptionalism narrative that once anchored the dollar’s premium valuation.
Yet even as the cyclical bearish case gains adherents, the broader question remains: does dollar weakness equate to de-dollarization? The short answer is: no, or at least not yet. The dollar still accounts for nearly 60 percent of global foreign exchange reserves, more than 50 percent of global trade invoicing, and nearly 90 percent of global foreign exchange transactions. Despite short-term market aversion — for central banks, commodity traders, and multinational corporations — the dollar remains indispensable. Its liquidity, the depth of US capital markets, and the breadth of dollar-denominated instruments such as US corporate bonds, Treasurys, and dollar-pegged financial products continue to make it the default global currency.
Incremental signs of de-dollarization are emerging, particularly in Asia and among members of the expanded BRICS bloc. The Association of Southeast Asian Nations (ASEAN) has actively committed to increasing the use of local currencies in intra-regional trade, aiming to reduce exposure to dollar volatility and geopolitical leverage. Countries such as China, India, and South Korea have increased currency swap agreements, promoted bilateral trade settlements in their own currencies, and repatriated portions of their foreign-held assets. Asian institutional investors, including life insurers and pension funds in Japan and Taiwan, have raised hedge ratios on dollar exposure, gradually shifting portfolio balances toward local currencies.
US Foreign Exchange Reserves in Millions of USD, 2010 – present
Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)
The BRICS alliance, recently expanded to include members such as Iran, Egypt, the UAE, and Indonesia, has amplified its political push toward de-dollarization. While the group remains economically diverse and geopolitically fragmented, its growing weight in global energy production, trade flows, and financial architecture reflects a strategic ambition to reduce reliance on the dollar. Joint liquidity pools, cross-border payment initiatives, and the creation of alternative commodity trading platforms further illustrate the group’s long-term objectives. Nonetheless, internal frictions within BRICS — particularly between China and India — and the absence of a truly unified financial infrastructure have limited hopes to erode dollar primacy.
A significant development in the de-dollarization narrative is the surge in official sector gold purchases. Central banks, particularly those aligned with or adjacent to China and Russia, have accumulated over 1,000 tons of gold annually for three consecutive years — doubling the pace of purchases seen in the 2010s. The European Central Bank now reports that gold accounts for 20 percent of global reserves, up sharply from previous levels to eclipse holdings of the euro itself. Meanwhile, the dollar’s share of global reserves has slipped from over 70 percent in 2000 to 57.8 percent in 2024. Gold’s role as a politically neutral store of value makes it an attractive hedge against both inflation and geopolitical risks, particularly in an environment where financial sanctions and reserve asset weaponization have grown more common.
Global Gold Demand (white) & Global Gold Demand Net Central Bank Purchases (blue), 2010 – present
(Source: Bloomberg Finance, LP)
Still, gold’s structural limitations mean that it is unlikely to fully supplant the dollar’s reserve currency functions. Even amid recent turmoil, global dollarization continues in many respects, particularly through the rapid expansion of dollar-based nonbank financial intermediation, dollar-denominated debt issuance, and the technological proliferation of dollar-linked stablecoins.
In sum, dollar weakness and de-dollarization are not synonymous. The recent depreciation of the dollar relative to other currencies reflects a complex interplay of trade disputes, fiscal excesses, cyclical capital flows, and risk sentiment shifts.
True de-dollarization, by contrast, requires the sustained development of viable alternatives that can match the dollar’s liquidity, legal protections, and institutional depth — an outcome that remains distant, though not unimaginable over the long term. While policymakers and market participants should not dismiss the slow, grinding adjustments occurring at the margins, the dollar nevertheless remains firmly entrenched as the central pillar of global finance.
A more sobering truth is this: the greatest threat to continued dollar dominance comes not from external challengers but within. Persistent fiscal indiscipline, rising debt-to-GDP ratios, erratic policy shifts, and the politicization of monetary and financial institutions collectively erode the confidence that anchors reserve currency status.
If that erosion continues, the dollar may eventually cede ground — not through a sudden collapse, but through the gradual accumulation of self-inflicted wounds. In the meantime, the world remains tethered to King Dollar, even as it cautiously explores alternatives.
Read More:
The Dollar and its Domestic Enemies
BRICS 2025: Expansion, De-Dollarization, and the Shift Toward a Multipolar World
The Techno-Industrial Policy Playbook, published by American Compass, The Foundation for American Innovation, The Institute for Progress, and New American Industrial Alliance (NAIA) Foundation, is being sold as a bold new blueprint for American renewal. It proposes that the federal government directly invest in politically chosen “strategic sectors,” led by a National Investment Council and a presidential Chief Investment Officer.
The message is simple: America must compete with China, rebuild its industrial base, and restore national greatness. But the policy prescription is anything but conservative. It’s industrial policy — a warmed-over central planning scheme that expands government authority in the name of economic vitality.
As someone grounded in free-market economics and classical liberal principles, I have three core objections to the playbook, each based on sound economic theory and real-world evidence.
First, the playbook misdiagnoses the source of American industrial decline, blaming free markets for problems caused by government failure. Second, it wrongly glorifies manufacturing as the benchmark for national success while ignoring technological progress and worker preferences. Third, it proposes top-down interventions that will entrench bureaucracy, reward special interests, and ultimately slow economic growth. This playbook doesn’t revive “conservative” economics — it replaces it with technocratic nationalism that looks more like progressive central planning than anything resembling liberty or limited government.
Let’s walk through each issue.
National conservatives claim that free markets abandoned America’s heartland. In reality, government failure drove investment away. Rust Belt cities like Detroit, Cleveland, and Buffalo didn’t wither because of capitalism. They collapsed under decades of poor policy choices: excessive taxation, inflexible labor unions, hostile zoning rules, bloated public payrolls, failing schools, and declining public safety. Businesses didn’t leave out of disloyalty — they left because politicians made it unprofitable to stay.
Meanwhile, jobs and capital flowed to states that protected economic freedom and other countries where it was more profitable. States like Texas, Florida, Tennessee, and even Colorado have outperformed many of their peers through stronger spending limits, more predictable tax environments, and competitive labor markets. Where policymakers trusted people over bureaucracies, prosperity followed. That’s not a failure of capitalism — it’s a case study in how markets respond to better limits on government, though those states could use more limits.
The playbook also claims that manufacturing is the backbone of national strength. That’s a romanticized notion more than a modern reality. America hasn’t deindustrialized — we’ve modernized. The US remains the world’s second-largest manufacturer, accounting for about 17 percent of global output. Real manufacturing production has nearly doubled since the 1990s. What’s declined is manufacturing employment, largely because of productivity gains. Machines now do what workers used to. That’s not a decline. That’s economic progress. The push to bring back those jobs, even through heavy subsidy or coercion, misses what most Americans actually want. They don’t long to return to factory floors. They seek flexible, meaningful, and often service-oriented careers in tech, finance, or entrepreneurship. We shouldn’t funnel workers back into yesterday’s economy. We should expand their freedom to pursue tomorrow’s opportunities.
Then comes the playbook’s solution: scaling up Washington’s power to steer markets in the name of national interest. But no matter how strategic the branding, this is just central planning. And it’s built on a false premise — that bureaucrats in DC can outthink millions of decentralized choices made each day by individuals and businesses. History has repeatedly shown what happens when the government takes the reins. Solyndra wasted over $500 million in taxpayer funds. The CHIPS Act has been a disaster. COVID-era spending lost more than $200 billion to fraud and waste. And DOGE.gov has flagged over $165 billion in wasteful government spending — more than $1,000 per taxpayer. These aren’t outliers. They’re baked into the cake of central planning.
The Department of Government Efficiency (DOGE) found wasteful spending of $233 million in DEI grants, including a $1 million program on “Antiracist Teacher Leadership.” The Department of Defense admitted to $80 million in wasteful spending. One government contract paid $181,000 for a climate advisor in Central Africa. More than 500,000 government credit cards were found active across 32 agencies. The estimated savings so far are $165 billion, or more than $1,000 saved per taxpayer. While this didn’t reach the $2 trillion proposed by Elon Musk, that wasn’t going to happen because doing so would require reducing welfare spending on mandatory programs like Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid. Congress must act now.
Friedrich Hayek explained why in The Use of Knowledge in Society: central authorities simply cannot gather and respond to the complex, dynamic information embedded in market prices. Even well-meaning planners can’t substitute for the distributed intelligence of free people responding to real signals, especially well-functioning market prices. James Buchanan’s public choice theory adds another layer: government actors are not immune to self-interest. They face incentives to reward donors, expand budgets, and serve entrenched interests, not to maximize efficiency or innovation.
So what should we do instead?
The answer isn’t to direct the economy from the top down. It’s to remove the barriers keeping people and businesses from thriving, as advocated by classical liberalism and embodied in many ways by freedom conservatism principles. Rather than expanding the state, we should limit it, sharpening its focus and unleashing its citizens.
That starts with sustainable budgeting. Government spending should be reduced and grow thereafter no faster than the rate of population growth plus inflation. Several states — like Texas, Iowa, North Carolina, and Colorado — have successfully implemented this principle, keeping government growth aligned with the average taxpayer’s ability to pay for it. We also need serious federal tax reform. The current code is riddled with carveouts, subsidies, and disincentives to save and invest. Flattening the tax structure and moving toward a consumption-based system would support long-term growth and reduce political manipulation. Extending the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act and spending less are keys for this year, but longer term, there is a need to substantially improve the tax system to fund only limited government spending.
Education is another cornerstone. Universal Education Savings Accounts (ESAs) by states, as the federal government should get out of education altogether, let parents — not politicians and bureaucrats — choose the best path for their children. That may be a government school, private school, homeschool, or trade school. Real choice drives real results. Healthcare deserves the same treatment. This includes restoring the doctor-patient relationship and lowering costs through no-limit Health Savings Accounts, Medicaid block grants to the states, and deregulated provider markets.
Perhaps most importantly, we must return to competitive federalism. Washington doesn’t have all the answers — and never will. States should be empowered to lead, compete, and innovate. That’s how policy improves and liberty expands. This means the federal government must reduce its roles in the executive, legislative, and judicial branches. Real community, too, can’t be centrally managed. National conservatives often argue that markets corrode culture. But in truth, voluntary exchange and personal responsibility create the conditions where community can thrive. Families, churches, and local institutions aren’t built by mandates — they’re built by people who are free.
The Techno-Industrial Policy Playbook represents a fundamental shift away from this understanding. It proposes that the solution to government failure…is more government. But those of us who believe in freedom know better. Liberty doesn’t need a five-year plan. It needs guardrails, not gates. It needs accountability, not committees. And it needs trust — in people, in markets, and in the timeless truth that free societies produce the most prosperous, dynamic, and moral outcomes the world has ever known.
It has been roughly a week since Israel launched its first air, drone, and special operations attacks on the Islamic Republic of Iran. Israel’s offensive, launched with the initially stated goal of eliminating Iran’s nuclear program, quickly evolved into an effort at regime destruction and replacement. In the fog of war, which spans from Tehran to the Oval Office, the Trump administration’s complicity and knowledge of the attack remain unknown. What is known, however, is that Israel’s actions have thrown into irreconcilable tension Trump’s two goals in the Middle East: depriving Iran of a nuclear weapon and avoiding open-ended conflict.
President Trump’s interventionist supporters are apt to point out that he has been consistent in his stance that Iran cannot be allowed to possess a nuclear weapon. Apparently lost on these neoconservative commentators is Trump’s consistently declared desire to end America’s forever wars, his routine condemnation of the nation-building project, and explicit denial of any desire to do so in Iran. Until a week ago, these two goals were not in tension as talks between the United States and Iran appeared productive.
But now, with Israel’s war on Iran, Trump’s stated policy preferences are clearly at odds, with interventionists now advocating for the United States to enter the war, either through “limited” strikes aimed at denuclearization or full-blown regime change. But to exercise either of those options would embroil his country in another Middle Eastern quagmire, unravel Trump’s coalition, and create more geopolitical problems than it would solve.
Some supporters of escalation, while publicly eschewing the idea of regime change, nevertheless support the idea of “limited” US strikes on Iran’s nuclear sites. Proponents of such a scheme compare the concept to that of Trump’s drone strike on Qasem Soleimani, a limited option that would yield significant benefits against comparatively little risk. One such supporter confidently quipped that “Trump vaporized Soleimani and then walked away. He can do it again here.”
This conflation constitutes magical thinking. Soleimani, while an essential figure within Iran’s Islamic Revolutionary Guard Corps (IRGC), was nonetheless a single man. He was also a liminal figure whose role blurred the lines between a state and a non-state actor. His assassination, aided by the IRGC designation as a terrorist organization, also provided a legal pretext, however flimsy. Furthermore, his killing in Iraq and the precision of the strike worked to limit the chance for blowback. None of these aspects would carry over to a potential US strike on Iran’s nuclear facilities, an action that would, by any reasonable definition, constitute an act of war.
There is also no guarantee that such strikes would succeed, at least not to the extent that they would outweigh the accompanying risks. Despite the views of airpower fetishists, air strikes alone would likely not be enough to destroy hardened facilities like the Fordow Fuel Enrichment Plant. Even supporters of such an option concede that the vaunted GBU-57 may be insufficient to eliminate the hardened Fordow facility. Such strikes on high-value targets would demand bomb damage assessments (BDA) performed by troops on the ground, likely in the form of an Israeli raid. Airpower, then, is not some magic talisman to achieve maximum effect with minimal risk.
Furthermore, strikes on hardened facilities, as tricky as they are, are but one issue; eliminating the scientific knowledge associated with nuclear technology is another. While, indeed, Israel has for years assassinated Iranian nuclear scientists, such efforts would need to remain active in perpetuity. Both of these hurdles, the tactical issues of destroying facilities and the strategic difficulty of degrading knowledge, undermine the fantasy that attacking Iran’s nuclear program can be “limited” in any sense of the word.
Beyond these material considerations, there is another, more perilous problem: Iran’s response to an overt act of war. Iran would assuredly view American attacks on their nuclear program as an assault on the regime itself, one that would undermine their legitimacy and would respond accordingly. Indeed, Iran’s supreme leader promised that “irreparable damage” would be visited upon US forces should they intervene in the war. While such threats are emanating from a severely weakened regime, they should not be taken lightly. American forces, scattered throughout the region, would present ample targets for Iran’s conventional weapons and proxy forces. What is more, while Israel has devastated Iran’s nuclear infrastructure, air defense, and command and control, the Islamic Republic’s army and navy remain comparatively untouched.
Therefore, even a “limited” strike on Iran’s nuclear program would quickly escalate into a general conflict. American entry into this war, even in a comparatively measured fashion, would nevertheless put the country on a glide path toward a more ambitious mission, one supported by key Republican politicians and Benjamin Netanyahu: regime change in Iran.
Entry into this war would scuttle Trump’s presidency and coalition. Despite hawkish claims to the contrary, reliable polling and other metrics strongly suggest shallow support for such an action. A recent YouGov poll found that even a majority of Republicans opposed military action, with only 19 percent supporting military intervention. Similarly, YouGov found that only 14 percent of Americans believed that Israel’s attacks on Iran would make the US safer. These polls are in line with earlier trends, which showed that young Republicans (like younger Americans generally) displayed a decreased level of support for Israel.
And, despite the claims of neoconservative supporters for intervention, the Republican base has displayed a lack of enthusiasm for open-ended, poorly defined proxy wars. This opposition is not merely dispersed in the electorate but is being voiced by MAGA stalwarts like Tucker Carlson, Marjorie Taylor Greene, Steve Bannon, and Charlie Kirk, to name a few. Whatever appetite there is for this war comes from the establishment Republican Party — namely, Senate leadership and the media orbit of legacy outlets like Fox News.
Entering this conflict would undermine one of President Trump’s key campaign promises and his own metric of presidential success, as outlined in his second inaugural address. “We will measure our success not only by the battles we win but also by the wars that we end — and perhaps most importantly, the wars we never get into.” Currently, the United States is not an active belligerent in this war. If that changes, then by his own standards, the Trump administration can be accurately judged as a failure.
In a recent blog post, Matt Yglesias chides northeastern Republicans for opposing pro-housing deregulation in state legislatures:
Republicans have led several major pushes for housing reform in red states. These efforts are inevitably GOP-led because these states have GOP-controlled legislatures, and to the best of my knowledge, none of them have met with uniform GOP opposition. But in New York and Maryland, we’ve seen divided Democrats unable to push through housing reforms supported by Democratic governors in the face of relentless GOP hostility.
He also references a recent bill that passed in Connecticut with exclusively Democratic support, Republican politicians in Virginia and New Jersey who have made statements against any attempts to legalize more home-building, and even a free-market Maine think-tank that opposes any diminution of local zoning powers.
So what’s the explanation? Yglesias’ own view is that “a perennial favorite activity of GOP-controlled state legislatures in places like Tennessee, Texas, and Georgia is passing laws to preempt local efforts to raise the minimum wage or otherwise lib out” (presumably referring to city-level gun control, tenant protections, and the like, as well as school policies on books, LGBT issues, and the like).
Because they’re used to preempting cities on other issues, preempting local zoning feels like a natural move for red-state Republican legislators, especially when they can focus it on larger cities and exempt suburbs and small towns, as recent legislation in Texas and Montana has done.
But “blue-state Republicans are anti-housing” doesn’t explain California, where Republicans from rural and inland areas joined just over half of Democrats in the state Senate to pass SB 79, requiring upzoning near transit stops. Of course, many Republicans in California are anti-housing – conservative Huntington Beach has even flirted with imposing strict rent control to stop apartment construction – but some of them are not.
Figure 1: Map of Freedom to Build, United States. Note: Constructed from Ruger and Sorens (2023), including only policies related to regulations on building housing.
Nationally, housing remains one of the last remaining cross-cutting issues: there are pro- and anti-housing Republicans just as there are pro- and anti-housing Democrats. Red states tend to regulate housing development less (Figure 1), but the causation probably runs from lack of strict zoning to partisanship rather than the other way around (Figure 2). The details make a difference, though. I remember speaking to a Republican Minnesota state senator a few years ago, who drew a distinction between types of housing. “We want more single-family, and the other side wants more multifamily.” (To date, Minnesota has failed to pass any statewide housing deregulation.)
Figure 2: Correlations Between Two-Party Presidential Vote in Various Years and Zoning Stringency in 2005, US Counties Note: Zoning stringency is measured by a survey of municipal land use officials. For presidential vote shares, higher values mean more Democratic support.
Some of the explanation for why northeastern Republicans oppose housing bills is that many of these housing bills have not been clearly deregulatory or have been nakedly partisan and left-wing, like the Connecticut bill, which strengthened rent regulation and enacted large giveaways to labor unions on top of its pro-housing measures. In other cases, good legislation like Massachusetts’ MBTA Communities Act has attracted Republican opposition (despite support from then-Governor Charlie Baker) because of its focus on zoning for multifamily housing, which is assumed to be mostly occupied by renters rather than condominium owners.
We should also question whether northeastern Republicans are always opposed to statewide pro-housing legislation. In Vermont, Republicans overwhelmingly supported 2023’s S 100 (now Act 47), relaxing the stringent requirements of the state’s environmental policy act, known as Act 250, and it passed into law easily. Last year, they opposed H 687 (now Act 181), which liberalized multifamily housing in infill locations while restricting suburban and rural development, but it passed over Gov. Phil Scott’s veto. In New Hampshire, Republican legislators are probably about 55 percent anti-housing and 45 percent pro-housing, depending on the bill, but every major center-right organization, including the free-market Josiah Bartlett Center, the socially conservative Cornerstone Action, the Business and Industry Association, Americans for Prosperity, and the New Hampshire Liberty Alliance, supports zoning reform.
What drives these differences in Republican views across states? The answer lies in a combination of factors.
Beginning in the 1970s, a conservative property rights rebellion began in the western states. The “wise use” movement, as it came to be called, also took hold in Vermont, where I once spoke to a group called Citizens for Property Rights that originally formed to oppose Act 250. This movement was a reaction to environmentalist land-use regulation, and traces of that pro-property rights mentality survive to a greater extent among western Republicans than among northeastern ones. But western Republicans aren’t uniformly supportive of property rights, as we’ve seen in Colorado, where most (but not all) Republicans have voted against housing deregulation.
As already mentioned, individual bills can be tilted for or against traditional Republican priorities. Unsurprisingly, in states where Democrats control the legislature, successful housing legislation tends to be tilted toward Democratic priorities (supporting unions, retaining or enhancing some environmental reviews, promoting multifamily over single-family, regulating rents, etc.).
In metro areas with a history of political trauma related to urban riots, forced busing, and related issues, Republicans tend to be more protective of the suburbs and don’t mind a high-cost housing wall around cities that, to their minds, keeps urban problems at bay. The work of political scientists Jessica Trounstine, Eitan Hersh, and Clayton Nall strongly supports various elements of this conjecture.
The last one in particular seems to help explain why so many right-wing activists in New Hampshire oppose zoning reform. I have tried to have reasonable conversations with them about what underlies their objections, and once we clear away the rationalizations about “local control” and so on, I can sometimes get to what seems to be their authentic fear: that these bills will allow for high-rise apartment buildings that will import impoverished criminals.
That fear seems out of all proportion to what these bills would actually do. Their main target this year was Senate Bill 84, which essentially would have required towns to have some place where you’re allowed to build a house on two acres. Two acres! Far from solving the housing affordability problem, this bill would simply have curbed some of the grossest excesses of “expropriation-by-regulation” in New Hampshire towns. Still, because of the outcry, it was retained in committee in the House after easily passing the Senate.
My impression, admittedly anecdotal, is that most of the vociferous opponents of zoning reform in New Hampshire grew up near Boston or New York, and have internalized the view that zoning is some kind of symbolic totem with which to stave off the darkness. The details of legislation don’t matter; what matters is maintaining the status quo at all costs. By contrast, Republican farmers in rural northern New England have the same mentality as western ranchers and miners: hands off my property! In Vermont, remote, rural, and stagnant enough to lack a big suburban Republican constituency, and in New Hampshire, which has a uniquely large libertarian bloc in the Republican Party, Republican YIMBYism stands a chance that it might not, unfortunately, in the rest of the Northeast, with the possible exception of Pennsylvania.
If these conjectures are correct, getting Republicans to support pro-housing-supply reform in the Northeast and Midwest will require: 1) moderate bills that put as much emphasis on freeing up land for single-family development as they do on new rental housing, and 2) a focus on solutions like speeding up permitting, compensation for regulatory takings, and neighborhood-option upzoning that leave the symbolic core of zoning untouched.
The Trump administration has increased tariff rates on dozens of countries in part to kickstart trade policy negotiations. These tariffs include 10 percent tariffs on dozens of countries, tariffs of over 30 percent on China, 50 percent tariffs on steel and aluminum, and 25 percent tariffs on autos. While the specifics of each negotiation will vary depending on the country’s role in the global economy and its current trade laws, there are three high-level goals relevant to all countries Trump should pursue. If he is successful, these negotiations will make US manufacturers more competitive, keep prices low for consumers, improve America’s ability to confront China, and help reduce the risk of a global trade war.
The US Court of International Trade recently ruled that many of Trump’s tariffs are illegal, but they’ve been allowed to remain in place pending appeal. In the meantime, Trump’s administration is discussing trade policy with several countries. This is wise since keeping the tariffs in place long-term will hurt the USeconomy. The Penn Wharton Budget Model estimates that Trump’s reciprocal tariff plan would reduce GDP by 6 percent and wages by 5 percent if it became permanent. A middle-income household would face a long-term income loss of $22,000. This income loss would offset nearly 15 years of tax savings that the average family receives from the Tax Cuts and Jobs Act, Trump’s signature tax plan from his first term.
The primary goal of Trump’s trade negotiations should be to expand trade by reducing tariff rates and other trade barriers. Here are three ways his administration could achieve this goal.
First, negotiate zero-for-zero tariffs on manufacturing inputs that would remove tariffs on inputs needed by USmanufacturers. These could be modeled on the terms contained in the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) that expanded access to intermediate inputs for thousands of small and medium-sized US manufacturers, allowing them to expand production and increase jobs for American workers. Agreeing to similar terms with other countries would ensure American manufacturers can get the materials they need to produce high-quality products.
Second, negotiate the elimination of non-tariff foreign trade barriers that inhibit US exports, US foreign direct investment, and US electronic commerce. Trade barriers include laws, regulations, policies, and practices—including non-market policies and practices—that distort or undermine competition. Examples include inadequate intellectual property protections, local content requirements, export subsidies, and unnecessary safety or sanitary standards. Country-specific examples that should be reformed are provided annually by the United States Trade Representative in its National Trade Estimate Report on Foreign Trade Barriers.
Third, negotiate tougher trade enforcement provisions to prevent China and other countries from evading US trade laws by rerouting exports to the United States through other countries. Countries should agree to allocate more resources to the enforcement of trade laws and verifying the country of origin of the goods that cross their borders. This would protect US consumers and firms from illegal or unsafe goods and help maintain the integrity of the global trade system.
Reducing tariffs on manufacturing inputs, eliminating non-tariff trade barriers, and improving enforcement of US trade laws would help the Trump administration accomplish several of its goals. First, US exports would be more competitive, which would boost manufacturing output and create jobs. Second, the cost of inputs would be reduced, and reciprocal tariff rates could be lowered, which would help keep consumer prices low. Third, by enhancing enforcement of US trade laws, the administration would be better equipped to address China’s objectionable trade policies without unduly inhibiting mutually beneficial trade with friendlier countries.
Nations that close themselves off from the world stagnate and fail. The best known example is China’s inward turn that started in the fifteenth century and lasted until the late twentieth. China missed out on the industrial revolution and by the 1800s it had dramatically fallen behind the West. Today, it is still playing catch-up.
Trump has an opportunity to improve international trade policy and ensure that America plays a leading role in the global economy for decades to come.